SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.16 issue3To sequestrate or not to sequestrate in view of the National Credit Act 34 of 2005: a tale of two judgmentsThe constitutionality of a biological father's recognition as a parent author indexsubject indexarticles search
Home Pagealphabetic serial listing  

Services on Demand

Article

Indicators

Related links

  • On index processCited by Google
  • On index processSimilars in Google

Share


Potchefstroom Electronic Law Journal (PELJ)

On-line version ISSN 1727-3781

PER vol.16 n.3 Potchefstroom Jan. 2013

 

ARTICLES

 

The unilateral determination of price - a question of certainty or public policy?

 

 

HM du Plessis

Hanri M du Plessis. LLB, LLM (UP). Lecturer, Department of Private Law, School of Law, UNISA. Email: dplesh@unisa.ac.za. This article is a summary of and adaptation from the author's LLM dissertation Du Plessis HM The Uni/atera/ Determination of Price in Contracts of Sa/es Governed by the Consumer Protection Act 68 of2008 (LLM dissertation UP 2012). Special recognition is given to Prof Chris Nagel (the author's LLM supervisor) for his expert guidance, support, encouragement and patience in the writing of the dissertation from which this article has been adapted

 

 


SUMMARY

The unilateral determination of price has been a controversial issue for an extended period of time. During the 1990s the Supreme Court of Appeal asked if the rule should still form part of South African law. Specifically, the court raised a few questions in respect of the rule and commented that the rule as applied in South African law is illogical. The court also remarked that public policy, bona fides and contractual equity might also be employed when considering such issues. Despite the criticisms of the Supreme Court of Appeal, it would seem that the rule still forms part of our law. This article investigates whether or not the rule should be retained in the South African common law. The answer will depend on two separate questions: Is the rule a manifestation of the requirement of certainty of price? If not, does public policy require that the rule be retained? The article shows that the rule prohibiting the unilateral determination of price should not be seen as a manifestation of the requirement of certainty of price. This is because there are various circumstances where the unilateral determination of the price results in certainty of price or can be applied in such a way as to arrive at certainty of price. Most of these arguments require that the discretion to determine the price should not be unfettered and should be subject to some objective standard. This can be done expressly or tacitly in the contract, or an objective standard (in the form of reasonableness) will be implied by law. Thereafter, the article considers various public policy considerations that could be used to determine if a discretion to determine the price should be enforced. The article argues that public policy may dictate that such a discretion should be valid and enforceable provided that it is not unfettered and subject to an external objective standard or reasonableness. However, in cases where an unfair bargaining position is present, public policy may dictate otherwise. The article accepts that whether a term providing for the unilateral determination of the price would be contrary to public policy or not will depend on the facts of the case. However, it is submitted that, at a minimum, the considerations and factors discussed in the article should be taken into account when making such an assessment.

Keywords: Certainty of price; Contracts of sale; Contractual autonomy; Contractual discretions; Public policy; Unequal bargaining relationship; Unilateral price determination


 

 

1 Introduction

It has been an established rule of South African law that "[t]here can be no valid contract of sale if the parties have agreed that the price is to be fixed in the future by one of them".1 Prior to 1993 the rule was firmly established in South African law and regularly applied by South African courts.2 The courts accepted the application of the rule, but interpreted and applied it in different ways. This casuistic approach led to different results, to legal uncertainty and sometimes even to undesirable results.3 Then in Benlou Properties (Pty) Ltd v Vector Graphics (Pty) Ltd4 the Supreme Court of Appeal criticised the rule but stated that despite these criticisms it is still bound "by the view of our old authorities".

During the 1990s the steep increase in interest rates triggered a number of High Court cases attacking the standard discretionary clauses in loan agreements, which provide for the adjustment of the interest rate at the lender's discretion.5 This question was referred to the Supreme Court of Appeal in NBS Boland Bank Ltd v One Berg River Drive CC; Deeb v ABSA Bank Ltd; Friedman v Standard Bank of SA Ltd.6 The question before the court was whether or not a clause providing a party with the discretion to fix the performance of the other party is valid and enforceable in our law. The court set three requirements for a discretionary power to fix performance to be valid and enforceable: firstly, the discretion is not to fix a purchase price or rental payable;7 secondly, the discretion is to fix the performance of the other party;8 and, thirdly, the discretion must be exercised arbitrio boni viri.9

Although the matter before the court was in respect of a discretion granted to a lender to adjust the interest rate, the court did refer to the rule that a sale agreement is invalid if one of the parties is given the power to determine the purchase price payable.10 The court raised a few questions in respect of the rule and commented that the rule as applied in South African law is "illogical".11 The court also remarked that public policy, bona fides and contractual equity might also be employed when considering such issues.12 However, the court made it clear that all of these comments were made obiter.13 Despite the criticisms of the Supreme Court of Appeal, it would seem that the rule still forms part of our law.14 This article investigates whether or not the rule should be retained in the South African common law. The answer to this question will depend on two separate questions: Is the rule a manifestation of the requirement of certainty of price? If not, does public policy require that the rule be retained?

 

2 The rule as a manifestation of the requirement of certainty of price

2.1 Introduction

In general terms, a contract can be defined as "an agreement made with the intention of creating an obligation or obligations".15 In other words, the parties must have the intention to be bound by the terms of the agreement. The enforcement of such agreements will be possible only if the obligations that the parties are binding themselves to are certain or can be ascertained.16 As such, it is an accepted legal principle that the terms of a contract must result in certainty regarding their legal consequences.17 This usually implies that the parties must clearly state the material aspects of the obligations and how they should operate.18 No contract can exist if the agreement is so vague that its material aspects and obligations cannot be determined.19

The price is an essential element of a contract of sale.20 Certainty of price is therefore a requirement for a contract of sale in South African law.21 In 1964 the requirement of certainty of price was formulated in Burroughs:22

It is, I think, clear that there can be no valid contract of sale unless the parties have agreed, expressly or by implication, upon a purchase price. They must fix the amount of that price in their contract or agree upon some external standard by the application whereof it will be possible to determine the price without further reference to them. ... Moreover, in our law, which does not conform in this regard with certain other systems, there can be no valid contract of sale if the parties have agreed that the price is to be fixed by one of them or by his nominee.

The above formulation was approved in a number of cases - including cases before the Supreme Court of Appeal.23 It is clear that a price must be determined in the contract itself or be capable of determination in accordance with some external standard.24 An external standard would refer to an objective one.25 Furthermore, it must also be determined without further reference to the parties.26 It appears that this would mean that the parties may not agree that one of them has the power to determine the price.27 In a case such as this it would appear that a discretionary power granted to one of the parties to determine the price would render the sale void in South African law.28

As shown above, the rule is traditionally viewed as a manifestation of the requirement of certainty of price. However, this view is not without criticism. The arguments for and against the rule dealing with the requirement of certainty of price are investigated below.

2.2 Arguments that the unilateral determination of price does not comply with the requirement of certainty of price

There are four main arguments in support of the assertion that a unilateral determination of price does not comply with the requirement of certainty of price and that this uncertainty cannot be remedied. They are: (a) the unilateral determination of price excludes agreement on one of the essential elements of a contract of sale; (b) the unilateral determination of price amounts to a pure potestative condition; (c) the unilateral determination of price is too vague to be enforceable; and (d) the court should not make a contract for the parties.

Each of these arguments is investigated below.

2.2.1 A discretion to determine the price excludes agreement on one of the essential elements of a contract of sale

A tendency exists in South African law to distinguish between discretions granted in respect of essential elements of a contract and discretions granted in respect of non-essential elements of a contract.29

In respect of contracts of sale, Machanick v Simon30 can be mentioned. The court stated that the price left to the discretion of the buyer in Roman law was imperfect.31 The court stated that as the price is one of the essential elements of a sale, "there is no room for doubt in that case".32 The court held that this can be distinguished from non-essential discretions which must be exercised arbitrio boni viri.3 This distinction was followed in subsequent case law.34

This distinction is based on the argument that a discretion to determine the price renders the contract void because consensus on an essential element of the sale (ie the price) is lacking.35 This view is open to criticism. Laing argues that the reason for the requirement of certainty of price is to "place the price beyond the reach of consensus" and to ensure that no further agreement is necessary to determine the final price.36 Where one of the parties is given the power to determine the price, no further agreement is necessary and there is consensus on the essential element of price.37 The party must merely exercise the discretion and determine the price. This is supported by the criticism in Benlou case,38 where the court remarked that it could not understand why the purchase price determined by a third party is more certain than the purchase price determined by one of the parties to the contract. Subsequently, the court in NBS Boaand Bank9 agreed with the criticism and expressed doubt as to the reasons for the distinction between a discretion to determine the price and other contractual discretions.

This distinction between discretions dealing with essential and non-essential terms was also applicable to the rent in a lease agreement. However, in Genac Properties40the court was willing to enforce a discretion that entitled the landlord to determine expenses to be paid (as part of the rent), because the court was of the view that it referred to an objective standard (the expenses were limited to expenses actually and reasonably incurred). This reasoning was followed in Engen Petroleum Ltd v Kommandonek (Pty) Ltd.41The court held that a clause providing for the adjustment of the rental in the landlord's discretion is valid if it refers to an objective and reasonable discretion.42

There no longer seems to be a good reason for distinguishing between price discretions and other discretions,43 especially on the ground that price discretions exclude agreement on one of the essential elements of a contract of sale.

2.2.2 A discretion to determine the price amounts to a pure potestative condition

There is a tendency to equate a discretion to determine the price with a pure potestative condition.44 The first reference in South African law to this argument can be found in Judge Wessels's reasoning in the Dawidowitz case. In this case the defendant pleaded that he and the plaintiff had agreed that he could pay the purchase price in monthly instalments, the amount of such instalments to be according to what the defendant could afford to pay.45 This case did not actually deal with a discretion to determine the price, but with how the price should be paid.46 Judge President De Villiers held that the defendant had not proved the agreement.47 Although Wessels concurred with De Villiers's judgment, he went further and discussed the general principles applicable to sale:

Our law requires, as one of the elements of a contract of sale, that there shall be a certain price. It may very well be that, from the circumstances of the case, the Court will imply that the purchaser was to pay a reasonable sum for the goods which he received. But if you cannot gather this from the surrounding circumstance, if there is no price, there is no contract. If I say, for instance: 'I will buy your horse for what I think it is worth', or: 'for what I choose to pay for it,' there is no sale. This principle applies to every form of contract. If a person who claims that he has made a contract proves that it depends wholly on his own will what part of it he should perform, then according to my view there is no contract; it is void for vagueness48 (my emphasis).

Clearly, Wessels held that a discretion to determine the price ("I will buy your horse for what I think it is worth") amounted to a pure potestative condition ("it depends wholly on his own will what part of it he should perform").49 This argument is open to criticism and must not be followed because a discretion to determine the price cannot be equated with a discretion to determine whether or not to be bound to the agreement.50

Reference must also be made to Theron v Joynt,51 where the court stated as follows:

Waar een van twee mense, wat voorgee kontrakterende partye te wees, hom die reg voorbehou om na willekeur enige beding in die sogenaamde ooreenkoms eensydig te wysig, kom sy regposisie in alle opsigte ooreen met dié van iemand wat oënskynlik 'n verpligting aangaan op voorwaarde dat hy na willkeur daardie verpligting kan nakom of ontduik. Sulke handelinge beskou ons reg as geen regshandelinge nie of handelinge sonder regsgevolge. (D 45 1 17; 45 1 46 3; 45 1 108 1).

The meaning of the term "willekeur" is uncertain.52 In Benlou Properties53 the court interpreted "willekeur" as a determination of price which "depends entirely on the will of one of the parties". In NBS Boland Bank54 the court stated that even if it refers to a discretionary power, the authorities listed by Deputy Chief Justice Van Heerden do not support his argument because all of these texts refer to a pure potestative condition. This was approved by the court in the Erasmus case,55 where the court held that a discretion to amend the terms of a contract does not amount to a pure potestative condition.

A further argument is that such a discretion amounts to a pure potestative condition because it is uncertain whether the party will ever determine the price.56 Laing57 counters this argument as follows: first, such uncertainty has not prevented the recognition of third-party price determinations. Secondly, the failure to determine the price could possibly be construed as a breach of contract and be dealt with accordingly.

2.2.3 A discretion to determine the price is too vague to be enforceable

In NBS Boland Bank58 the court stated the following:

A recurring theme in those cases in which it was held that the clause in question is invalid is that a contract which empowers one of the parties to fix a prestation is void for vagueness. With one exception that was undoubtedly the view of Roman-Dutch law writers in regard to the determination of the price in a sale and the rental in a lease.

In his commentary on the above extract, Kerr59 remarks that there is no reference in Roman-Dutch law supporting the view that a contract allowing for the determination of the price by one of the parties is void for vagueness. However, there are cases in South African law that do support such a view and almost all of these cases cite Dawidowitz as authority.60 This is probably because the first mention of vagueness in respect of a discretion to determine the price is found in this case, where the court stated as follows:

[I]f there is no price, there is no contract. If I say, for instance: 'I will buy your horse for what I think it is worth', or: 'for what I choose to pay for it,' there is no sale. This principle applies to every form of contract. If a person who claims that he has made a contract proves that it depends wholly on his own will what part of it he should perform, then according to my view there is no contract; it is void for vagueness61 (my emphasis).

As shown above, a discretion to determine the price is not the same as a contract where the party can decide whether he wants to be bound to the contract or not.62 Such a contract is also not void for vagueness. Vagueness refers to "indefinite terms", terms "not definitely or precisely expressed" or "deficient in details or particulars".63 In respect of words and language, it means "[n]ot precise or exact in meaning".64 Therefore, vagueness refers to a contract where the intention of the parties cannot be determined because the terms are indefinite, imprecise, insufficient or unclear in their meaning and, consequently, the contract is void for vagueness.65

Where one of the parties is in clear language given the power to determine the price, the agreement cannot be described as vague.66 The only thing that is not certain is the eventual price.67 However, the moment the price is determined, this uncertainty disappears.68 Another example of such a contract is a contract of sale where the price is to be determined by a third party. Such contracts are not considered void for vagueness.69

A further argument that the contract is void for vagueness is that it is uncertain how the eventual price should be determined. If the party with the discretion fails to determine the price, what guidelines must the court follow to make such a determination? It is argued below that in the absence of guidelines in the contract itself the court should imply that such a discretion should be exercised arbitrio boni viri.70 It will also be shown that there are principles and guidelines that could be followed to make such a determination.71

2.2.4 The principle that the courts should not make a contract for the parties

Kerr argues that the unilateral determination of price according to the standard arbitrio boni viri should not be allowed. One of the reasons for his view is that such an interpretation would result in the same problems encountered in third-party price determinations.72 Where there is a dispute, the court acting in the place of a reasonable person will have to determine the price or set the contract aside.73 Kerr74 argues that this will breach the principle that the courts should not make a contract for the parties. In support of his argument, Kerr75 refers to the H Merks case. However, in this case the parties agreed that the "price may be increased by mutual agreement from time to time".76 This can be distinguished from the unilateral determination of price where no further agreement is required. Alternatively, this principle is usually applied where there is uncertainty as to what the parties intended.77 This is not the case in discretions to determine the price as the parties' intention is usually clear. Furthermore, this principle could be tempered by the application of the maxim ut res magis valeat quam pereat.78 Where this is not possible (as in the case of a clearly unfettered discretion), the courts will not be willing to imply an ex lege term of reasonableness and determine the price for the parties.79

2.3 Arguments that the unilateral determination of price does comply with the requirement of certainty of price or does not need to

There are also arguments that the unilateral determination of price does comply with the requirement of certainty of price or does not need to. The following main arguments are investigated:

(a) the use of the word "imperfectum" in D 18 1 35 1;

(b) where the discretion refers to an objective or external standard;

(c) the standard of arbitrio boni viri should apply to such discretions;

(d) the discretion can be granted to either the seller or the buyer;

(e) the contract should be interpreted in favour of its validity, and

(f) the contract could be enforced as an innominate contract.

2.3.1 The use of the word "imperfectum " in D 18 1 35 1

In Benlou Properties the court considered the interpretation of D 18 1 35 1 by the Roman-Dutch writers and Daube's contradictory arguments.80 The court stated the following:

According to Daube there is much to be said for a construction that the text does not condemn a sale as invalid if the price is to be fixed by the buyer, but merely provides that the sale is imperfectum until the price has been fixed.81

In NBS Boland Bank82 the court stated that "in some cases providing for discretional determinations there may be no enforceable contract until the determination is made. But when made an unconditional contract comes into being." The court was not specifically discussing a discretion to determine the price, but this would be a plausible interpretation that would allow for a valid contract as soon as the price was determined.

2.3.2 Where the discretion refers to an objective or external standard

In Burroughs Machines the court stated that the parties "must fix the amount of that price in their contract or agree upon some external standard by the application whereof it will be possible to determine the price without further reference to them".83 From the above formulation, it is clear that when the price is not fixed in the contract itself, it must be capable of determination in accordance with some external standard (which will be an objective standard).84 Furthermore, it should not be necessary to consult with the parties before determining the price. According to some writers, this would mean that there should be no further need to consult the parties to ascertain their intention.85 Therefore, no further agreement should be necessary to determine the final price.86 This would accord with the reason for the rule, namely, to "place the price beyond the reach of consensus".87 On this interpretation, where one of the parties may determine the price, the determination would not fall foul of this second requirement, as the price can be determined without any further agreement between the parties. However, such a discretion would still have to meet the first requirement, namely, it must refer to some external or objective standard.88 Such an interpretation has been viewed as an interpretation "stretching the limits of the meaning of the term 'objectively ascertainable'",89 but it is clear that our courts have been prepared to follow such an interpretation.

In Murray & Roberts90 the court was prepared to accept that an agreement between the parties that the price would have to be determined by one of the parties together with a third party would be valid because it would "on the face of things" refer to an objective and external standard. This was also the case in Stead v Conradie.91 In this case, a clause in a contract provided that one of the parties could determine the "current value" of the property, which would form the basis of the price to be paid.92 The court held that "current value" referred to the market value, which could be objectively ascertained.93 The court said that the discretion was not left to the absolute discretion of the party and therefore it was valid as it referred to an external standard, which could be determined without further reference to the parties.94

The courts have also been prepared to follow such an interpretation in respect of contracts of lease. In Proud Investments (Pty) Ltd v Lanchem International (Pty) Ltd95 the court had to decide whether a provision in a rental agreement providing for the tenant to be liable for certain costs incurred by the landlord was valid. The court a quo held that in effect the clause meant that the landlord could determine such costs in his discretion and therefore the clause was invalid.96 However, this decision was reversed on appeal. The court referred to the provisions in the contract that required that the costs had to be reasonable and any dispute concerning the reasonableness of the costs should be referred to the landlord's auditors.97 The auditors would act as experts and their decision would be final and binding on the parties.98 The auditors would have to consider the fair market costs of the services supplied and call for evidence from suitably qualified persons in making their decision.99 The Supreme Court of Appeal held that the discretion was valid as it did provide for an "objective determination of reasonableness ... by the landlord's auditors as expert outsiders without any reference to the landlord".100

In the case of Genac Properties101 the court stated that the discretion to determine expenses to be paid (as part of the rent) was objectively ascertainable because the expenses were limited to expenses actually and reasonably incurred. Therefore, the court held that the expenses were "not subject to the landlord's will or whim".102

In Benlou Properties103 the court stated that a discretion would be invalid if the rent could be determined in one of the party's unfettered discretion. As the discretion granted to the lessor to determine additional rent was subject to three qualifications, all of which referred to an objective standard, the court held that the clause was valid.104

In Engen Petroleum105 the lessee was granted the right to adjust the rental payable in terms of the lease agreement. However, such a right was subject to three requirements: firstly, the discretion might be exercised only on reasonable grounds; secondly, such a right would arise only if certain circumstances changed to make the continued performance of the lessee uneconomic; finally, the adjustment had to render the lessee's obligations economical as opposed to uneconomical. The court held that all these requirements referred to an objective standard which could be determined and, as such, the clause was valid.106

Therefore a discretion will be valid if it is subject to an external or objective standard and this could include a reference to reasonableness.107

2.3.3 The standard of arbitrio boni viri should apply to such discretions

The courts are also willing to read reasonableness into a discretion unless it is clear from the contract that the discretion is not subject to these standards.108 Therefore, once reasonableness is implied, the discretion refers to an objective standard and complies with the requirement of certainty of price.109

The court in NBS Boland Bank110 stated that "unless a contractual discretionary power was clearly intended to be completely unfettered, an exercise of such a discretion must be made arbitrio boni viri". The court referred to various previous cases supporting this proposition.111 In addition, the court referred to D 50 17 22.112

As discussed elsewhere, D 50 17 22 1 should be read together with D 18 1 7 pr.113These two texts deal with the sale of slaves and a condition imposed by the seller, namely, that the sale of the slave is conditional on his satisfaction of the accounts managed by the slave on his behalf.114 To ensure that the seller did not stall the sale for frivolous or captious reasons, the seller was required to make his judgment arbitrio boni viri.115 The Supreme Court of Appeal was prepared to deduce, from this passage, a general implied term of reasonableness applicable to all contractual discretions (save contracts of sale and lease). As the passage originally deals with a contract of sale, there does not seem to be any reason why the rule should not be extended to apply to the unilateral determination of price.116 The court itself also expressed doubt as to the reasons for the distinction between a discretion to determine the price and other contractual discretions.117 The court did not decide whether these principles should apply to a contract of sale or lease, but there seems to be authority in our case law for applying this principle to both types of contract.

Laing traced such authority back to 1909 in the case of Dickinson & Fisher v Arndt & Cohn.118 In this case the parties agreed that the price was subject to market fluctuations.119 The court held that this would mean "that the price may be increased at the option of the sellers ... upon fluctuation upwards in the market price".120 Therefore, before the price could be adjusted there had to be an increase in market prices.121 Furthermore, the court held that the adjustment of the seller might not result in a price "for too much".122 Although this does not explicitly refer to a reasonable discretion, it clearly refers to a limited discretion. Soon thereafter the court had to consider a contract of sale of a jeweller's business where the parties agreed that the price would be "the amount of the stock-in-trade at marked price less 15 per cent., provided always that in the event of the purchaser considering the cost price of any portion of the stock-in-trade as too high, he shall be entitled to decline to purchase same".123 As it happened, the buyer rejected the majority of the stock because he considered the marked prices as excessively high.124 The seller argued that the buyer's argument that he was entitled to reject the stock would amount to a claim to determine his own price, which was not allowed.125 The court held that the parties considered that the buyer was not likely to reject the stock mala fide as he would need it in the new business, which indicated that the parties intended that he would act bona fide.126 Finally, the court held that in line with the principle of freedom of contract, the parties could leave a condition of the contract to the discretion of one of them and that in the present case such a discretion had to be exercised bona fide.127

In respect of contracts of lease, this type of reasoning reflects in the more recent cases of Benlou Properties and Engen Petroleum, which deal with a discretion to adjust the rental in a lease agreement.128

If these principles should apply to a discretion to determine the price in a contract of sale, it is necessary to determine the meaning of the phrase arbitrio boni viri. On various occasions the courts have discussed the standard against which a discretionary power must be tested. Despite earlier indications that the standards of arbitrio boni viri and reasonableness can be distinguished from each other,129 cases that are more recent indicate that arbitrio boni viri would refer to a reasonable discretion.130 In the Juglal case131 the court held that the person must "act reasonably and ... exercise a reasonable discretion". This would refer to an objective standard.132 In the Erasmus case133 the court referred to the dictionary meaning of arbitrio boni viri, namely, "the decision of a good man", which is explained as "a reasonable decision". The court has also held that in the current-day context this would mean "the judgment of a fair-minded person".134

In Erasmus135 the court held that "the concept of reasonableness is so settled in our law that it can readily be used, and is used, as an objective standard that is justiciable by a court". The fact of the matter is that the courts are comfortable and familiar with working with terms such as "fairness" and "reasonableness" and already there are various guidelines laid down that could be used in such an assessment.136 Generally, the courts have referred to the dictionary meaning of "reasonable", namely that which is equitable or fair, and not asking too much.137 In respect of contractual discretions, the courts have considered the following factors to determine whether or not the discretion was exercised reasonably:

(a) the intention of the parties when the contract was concluded;138

(b) the facts of the particular case (ie the terms and circumstances of the contract);139

(c) the viewpoint of both parties in order to achieve a balance between the interests of both parties;140

(d) the commercial rationality of the decision measured against a reasonable man in the mercantile world,141 and

(e) what is customary and usual, which does not necessarily equate with what is fair and reasonable.142

In an article in response to the judgment in NBS Boland Bank, Otto143 reviewed all the relevant case law and compiled a list of guidelines or factors that could be used to test whether a discretion to adjust the interest rate was exercised reasonably. These factors could be adapted for use in discretions to determine the price. Such adjusted factors would include the following:

(a) contract terms dealing with how the price must be determined;144

(b) the prices "customarily levied ... at that particular time in respect of that class of customer", where the contract does not prescribe how the price should be determined;145

(c) price movements in the market for the same goods under the same circumstances;146

(d) general economic fluctuations;147 and

(e) prices charged by other sellers.148

It is clear that a discretion to determine the price should accord with the standard of arbitrio boni viri and that this should refer to a reasonable standard. The question that now arises is this: when can an unreasonable exercise of a discretion to determine the price be attacked and how must this be done? The court in NBS Boland Bank149 asked if the determination would be considered to be noncompliant "if it is merely unjust, or whether it must be manifestly unjust?" In this respect, the court was asking if the principles governing third-party price determinations should be applicable to a price determination by one of the parties.150 The analogy between third-party price determinations and unilateral price determinations would seem appropriate.151 Firstly, the third party is required to act reasonably in determining the price, which is the same standard as that required in a case of unilateral price determinations.152 Secondly, the problems faced in determining whether or not a unilateral determination of price was unreasonable are similar to those faced in third-party price determinations.153 Therefore, the principles applicable to third-party determinations will provide useful guidelines for testing unilateral price determinations.

Generally, if the third party does not fix the price there is no sale.154 Where this is due to the actions of one of the parties the situation is not clear, but there is authority to suggest that it should be dealt with as a fictional fulfilment of a condition or a breach of contract.155 In respect of the unilateral determination of a price it has been suggested that this could possibly be dealt with as a breach of contract.156

Where the price determined by the third party does not differ too much from the amount that might have been expected, the parties are bound to it.157 However, if the price falls outside this range it does not have to be paid or accepted.158 Such a price is referred to as a price that is "manifestly unjust", "manifestly unfair" or "altogether too high or too low".159 This manifestly unjust price is not void ipso facto but must be set aside by the court.160 The court can then replace the price determined by the third party with the price the court considers reasonable.161 The party attacking the third-party determination will have to put evidence before the court of what a reasonable determination would be, which will enable the court to determine a reasonable price.162 Once the court has determined the price, the non-aggrieved party (the party not disadvantaged by the price determined by the third party) then has the choice either to accept the court's determination or to resile from the contract.163 Different reasons are proposed for this rule.164 First, the court in Hurwitz165 stated that if the court quantifies the price the court's method will probably be different from the method that the parties agreed on. However, in the Van Heerden166 case the court stated that the right to resile comes into play rather because the parties should have a choice not to become involved in the time-consuming and expensive endeavour of obtaining the court's determination. Kerr167 suggests that whether or not a party should be bound by the court's decision would depend on the intention of the parties. Did they want the price to be determined by that specific third party alone or did they instead intend a reasonable determination?168 In the latter instance, it could be argued that the parties should be bound to the price determined by the court. It is submitted that the parties' intention should also be the determining factor when deciding if the parties must be bound to the court's determination in cases dealing with unilateral determinations of price.

2.3.4 The discretion can be granted to either the seller or the buyer

A further consequence of the principles discussed above and the criticisms levied at viewing price discretions as pure potestative conditions is that the discretion should be valid whether it is granted to the seller or the buyer (as long as it results in certainty of the price).

In NBS Boland Bank169 the court referred to the Roman-law texts dealing with pure potestative conditions. The court stated that all of these texts deal with a situation where the promissor has a right to determine his performance but do not deal with the situation where the promissee has the right to determine the promissor's obligation.170 Therefore the court held that where a party can determine the other party's performance such a contract is valid (provided the discretion must be exercised arbitrio boni viri), but did not answer the question of whether a party could determine his own performance.171

Subsequently the court in Erasmus172 held that a discretion granted to a party to determine his own performance would be allowed if the discretion was "subject to an objective standard and thus fettered". The court held that there is no reason to limit the rule that discretionary powers must be exercised arbitrio boni viri to discretions granted to the promissee.173

Therefore, if these principles are extended to apply to sales it would mean that a discretion granted to either the buyer or the seller would be valid, provided the discretion is not an unfettered one.

2.3.5 A contract should be interpreted in favour of its validity

It is an established principle that the courts should favour an interpretation that renders the contract valid rather than an interpretation that renders it void.174 This rule of interpretation refers to the maxim verba ita sunt intelligenda ut res magis valeat quam pereat.175

This is in accordance with the principle that the court should "rather try to help the parties towards what they both intended rather than obstruct them by legal subtleties and assist one of the parties to escape the consequences of all that he has done and all than he has intended".176 The court should not act as the destroyer of bargains but rather give operation to agreements made with a serious intention to be binding.177 This is in accordance with the public policy that agreements entered into freely should be enforced.178 This is probably one of the reasons why the courts are willing to imply that a discretion must be exercised reasonably rather that unfettered.179

Kerr180 concedes that this principle forms part of the rules of interpretation, but he argues that this principle should not be used to "validate an agreement which lacks consensus on an essential requirement". However, as shown above, such contracts do not lack consensus. Furthermore, the courts have referred to this principle when dealing with discretions to determine the performance of one of the parties.181

2.3.6 The contract can be enforced as an innominate contract

Some South African commentators argue that where a contract of sale fails because of uncertainty of price, the contract could possibly be enforced as an innominate contract.182 In Burroughs183 the court did not decide this issue but seemed doubtful that the courts would "ever enforce a purported sale in which the price is neither fixed nor determinable by reference to some stated external standard".

In Murray & Roberts184 the court dealt with an innominate contract, where the parties agreed that Murray & Roberts Construction together with a third party would determine the price at which certain stands would be sold to the public. However, the court held that the price was a material term of the contract and would have to be ascertained with reference to an external standard. The court stated explicitly that it was not laying down a general rule.185 However, the judgment is indicative that even if the court had been willing to view a contract granting one of the parties a discretion to determine the price as an innominate contract, such a discretion would also need to refer to an external standard where the price was a material term of the contract. As the standard for a certain price in a contract of sale would be identical to the standard required of a price in an innominate contract, regarding the contract as an innominate contract would take the issue no further.

2.4 Conclusion

It should be clear from the above discussion that the rule that prohibits the unilateral determination of price should not be seen as a manifestation of the requirement of certainty of price.186 There are various circumstances where the unilateral determination of the price results in certainty of price or can be applied in such a way as to arrive at certainty of price. Most of these arguments require that the discretion to determine the price should not be unfettered and be subject to some objective standard. These requirements may be incorporated into the contract (either expressly or tacitly) or an objective standard (in the form of reasonableness) will be implied by law.187

 

3 The rule and public policy

3.1 Introduction

As the requirement of certainty of price should not be used as the test against which a unilateral determination of price is tested, the validity of such discretions should rather be assessed against public policy.188

3.2 The concept of public policy

It is a fundamental principle of the law of contract that agreements made with a serious intention to be legally binding should be enforced.189 However, when a contract is against public policy it will not be enforced.190

The concept of public policy is difficult to define but it is generally accepted that a contract will be contrary to public policy if it runs counter to the interests of the community.191 In Barkhuizen v Napier192 the court defined public policy as "the legal convictions of the community". As the interests and views of the community change over time, public policy is not a static concept but subject to change.193 Firstly, the principles and rules governing public policy are subject to change.194 Secondly, public policy is also context-sensitive and dependent on the circumstances of the specific case.195 There is no specific formula or test which must be followed to determine whether or not a term in a contract is contrary to public policy.196 In most cases the courts weigh up various policy considerations or interests against one another to determine if a term in a contract would be contrary to public policy.197

The courts have set some rules that should be followed when embarking on a public policy investigation.198 Firstly, public policy is anchored in the values enshrined in the Constitution of the Republic of South Africa, 1996 (hereafter the Constitution)199 and the court must consider these values together with any other policy considerations.200 Secondly, the courts will be hesitant to declare a term contrary to public policy and will do so in clear cases only.201 Thirdly, the term itself must be contrary to public policy. Neutral terms that can be implemented in a way that would not be contrary to public policy will not result in the contract's being against public policy.202 Fourthly, the court will be cautious to declare a term contrary to public policy merely because it is against the court's individual feeling of justice or fairness.203

If a term is contrary to public policy, it will be unenforceable or void.204 The price is one of the essential elements of a contract of sale and without a price there can be no sale. Where a discretion to determine the price is contrary to public policy, there is no price and the contract will be void.

3.3 Policy considerations relevant to the unilateral determination of price

This discussion aims to identify and investigate considerations that may be relevant in determining whether a unilateral determination of price is against public policy or not. The following considerations or factors are discussed: (a) contractual autonomy and the sanctity of contracts; (b) the principle of simple justice between man and man; (c) the principle that the parties should (as far as possible) have equal bargaining power; and (d) practical considerations in favour of the unilateral determination of price.

3.3.1 Contractual autonomy and the sanctity of contracts

Generally, public policy demands that contracts entered into freely should be enforced.205 This is also the case in respect of contractual discretions. In Benlou Properties206 the court stated as follows:

Nor is there a policy reason why such an undertaking should be void merely because it relates to an exercise of discretion. Although pronounced in a different context, the following oft-quoted dictum of Sir George Jessel MR in Printing and Numerical Registering Co v Sampson (1875) LR 19 Eq 462 at 465 is apposite:

'... if there is one thing which more than another public policy requires it is that men of full age and competent understanding shall have the utmost liberty of contracting, and that their contracts when entered into freely and voluntarily shall be held sacred and shall be enforced by Courts of justice'.

In the case of Erasmus207 the court cited contractual autonomy as one of the reasons why a discretion to determine a party's own performance should be allowed.

When a party agrees to the unilateral determination of price by the other party, he is agreeing (and thus exercising his contractual autonomy) "to forfeit his autonomy regarding the determination of the consequences of the contract".208 Therefore, giving effect to the discretionary clause would be in accordance with the principle of contractual autonomy.209 Therefore it can be argued that public policy dictates that discretionary powers to determine the price should be valid.

The fact that a person should be allowed to determine his own matters, even to his detriment, has been held to refer to the constitutional values of dignity and freedom.210 Although contractual autonomy is an important policy consideration, it is not the only or the most important consideration.211 Other values in the Constitution (for example equity) may reduce the weight given to contractual autonomy.212

3.3.2 The principle of simple justice between man and man

In both of the cases referred to above, the court added a proviso that the discretion may not be unfettered.213 The court in Benlou214 referred to the rules governing the certainty of price for this proviso. However, in Erasmus215 the court referred to the fact that "all contracts are subject to the principle of good faith" and therefore extended discretionary powers to include the determination by a party of its own performance provided it did so arbitrio boni viri. Good faith is a factor that is taken into account when deciding whether a term is against public policy or not.216

Although the role of good faith in the concept of public policy is not very clear,217 good faith has been thought to inform the principle of simple justice between man and man.218 This principle requires that the parties' individual interests must be weighed against each other.219 The unreasonableness of a term against one of the parties must be weighed up against the interests of the other party, who is protected by the term.220 However, the courts will not hold a term as contrary to public policy merely because it is unreasonable or unfair to one of the parties to the contract.221 The term would have to go so far as to be contrary to the interests of the public.222 Where the term goes further than what would reasonably be necessary to protect the interest of the party in whose favour it is, this could indicate that the term is contrary to public policy.223 This could be the case where the effect of the term is to place one of the parties almost entirely in the economic power of the other party.224

As is shown below, there are practical considerations that would necessitate a discretion to determine the price.225 However, none of these would require the seller to reserve an unfettered discretion to determine the price. It is therefore not surprising that there is no authority in our case law that allows for an unfettered discretion.226 Kerr227 argues that this is because allowing unfettered discretions would result in a greater possibility of fraud or abuse by a party to impose unfair and unreasonable obligations. This would explain why the courts would require that a discretion to determine the price or the rent would need to be limited by an external objective standard or reasonableness.228 This further explains why the courts would read reasonableness into the discretion where possible.229

A further argument by Kerr230 is that the party alleging that the discretion was exercised unreasonably would have the onus to prove this. This can be very difficult where the buyer does not know what factors were taken into account in determining the price or how the price was set. In FW Knowles231 the court remarked that the person alleging that he has exercised his discretion reasonably and has good reasons alone can know what it consists of and should be obliged to establish it. However, the court did not decide this issue and accepted that the onus is on the party alleging that the discretion was exercised unreasonably to show that this occurred.232 This decision was confirmed in subsequent case law.233

In ABSA Bank Ltd v Lombard234 the court dealt with the discretion of a bank to adjust the interest rate in respect of a loan. The debtor placed evidence before the court that the bank increased the interest rate upon an increase in the prime lending rate, but failed to reduce the interest rate when the prime lending rate decreased.235 The court held that this evidence was enough to establish a prima facie case that the bank had exercised its discretion unreasonably.236 It is, of course, easier to prove this in the case of interest rates as all of them are linked to some interest rate or other (for example, the prime lending rate or the Reserve Bank rate) that can be determined with ease. However, using the guidelines and factors outlined above to determine reasonableness, it could be possible to establish a prima facie case for unreasonableness in respect of a discretion to determine or adjust a price. Specifically, the factors adjusted from those proposed by Otto in respect of interest rate discretions could provide good examples of the kind of evidence that could be put before the court to establish a prima facie case that the seller exercised his discretion unreasonably.237

3.3.3 The parties should (as far as possible) have equal bargaining power

As shown above, there is authority in our case law that supports a limited discretion, either because the discretion must be exercised reasonably or because the discretion refers to an objective or external standard.238 These standards would appear to overcome the possible problem that one of the parties might abuse such power.

Kerr239 argues that there is a further danger in allowing a limited discretion. His concern is in respect of limited discretions where an unequal bargaining position exists.240 This refers to the policy consideration that parties, as far as possible, should have equal bargaining power, which can be deduced from the underlying constitutional value of equality.241 Where an unequal bargaining position is present, the weight given to the principle of contractual autonomy (and the values of freedom and dignity) must be decreased.242

It has been said, and it is true, that market competition should temper this problem to some extent.243 However, Kerr244 argues that if such a discretion is allowed, dominant parties would include such discretions in their standard-form contracts. The other party would then either have to accept the determined price or attack the discretion.245 Attacking the discretion would be a time-consuming and expensive endeavour and, more often than not, the costs of attacking the discretion would exceed the determined price.246 Kerr's247 fear is that this would result in the dominant party's setting a price above the appropriate value "secure in the knowledge that few, if any, opposing contracting parties would be in a financial position to challenge the determination". There would seem to be some merit in this argument. However, an unequal bargaining position per se will not be enough to indicate that a term is contrary to public policy. This factor must be considered together with other relevant factors.248

Finally, unequal bargaining relationships are commonly found in consumer contracts. Kerr249 predicted that consumer legislation would influence whether or not the rule would remain a part of South African law. In this respect, the Consumer Protection Act 68 of 2008 ("the CPA") effects the application of the rule in contracts of sale governed by this Act. Section 23(3) of the CPA prohibits a retailer from displaying any goods for sale without displaying a price in relation to those goods.250 Section 23(6)(a) states that the supplier may not require a consumer to pay a higher price than the displayed price.251 If two prices are displayed concurrently in respect of the same goods, the retailer is bound to the lower displayed price.252 This would seem to exclude the possibility that the price can be determined by the seller's exercising an objective or reasonable discretion. However, section 48(1)(c) states that a consumer may waive a right provided such a waiver is not on unfair, unreasonable or unjust terms or provided such unfair, unreasonable or unjust terms are not imposed as a condition for entering into the transaction. This means that a discretion to determine the price could possibly be attacked as being an unfair, unreasonable or unjust term. The term must then be assessed by applying the test of fairness in section 48(2)253 and considering the list of factors set out in section 52(2).254 Once the price has been determined, the price would also be subject to section 48(1)(a)(i), which provides that a supplier may not offer to sell or enter into an agreement to sell any goods at a price that is unfair, unreasonable or unjust.255

3.3.4 Practical considerations in favour of the unilateral determination of price

Although practical considerations are not a policy consideration per se, they are relevant to establishing the purpose of the term in order to determine whether or not the term protects the interests of the favoured party more than reasonably necessary. There are a number of practical considerations that would favour (or even necessitate) the use of discretionary powers in respect of the price.256 As will be seen below, none of these would make it necessary for the seller to reserve an unlimited discretion to determine or adjust the price.

The discretion may be necessary as the final act to finalise the price.257 This could be the case where the contract contains a price escalation clause.258 Laing259 refers to the escalation clause in Burroughs, where the court had to consider an escalation clause dealing with a change in the manufacturing costs of the goods. As pointed out by Laing,260 the price does not automatically change if the manufacturing costs change: the seller would have to exercise a discretion to determine what the change was and apply such a change to the price.

It also possible that one of the parties may be better equipped to determine what the price change should be.261 Using the same example above, the seller would be in a better position to determine what the change in manufacturing costs is and how to apply this to the price.262 The buyer may not have the necessary knowledge, skills or capabilities to make such an assessment.263

Furthermore, it may not be possible for the parties to agree on a purely objective method for adjusting the price. If the unilateral determination of a price is not allowed, the parties would have to agree on any price change.264 This may not be practical or in the interests of the parties.265 This is especially true where there is an established and continuing relationship between the parties - for example, between a supplier and a supermarket.266 It would be impractical, costly and time consuming if the parties had to agree on every price change every time such a change occurred.267 The buyer may feel it is more important to ensure the supply of the goods and may not be too concerned about slight or marginal adjustments to the price.268 This can be illustrated by the fact that in the Westinghouse case269 the seller indicated that "98% of its customers accepted escalation clauses of this nature and were prepared to accept [its] figure of increased costs".

Finally, where a price escalation clause does not provide for a specific formula by which to calculate the price, it may result in the conclusion that "the determination of the amount of escalation might in the last resort be left to the decision of appellant [the seller]".270 This is especially true in cases where the escalation clause includes increases that would be more difficult to determine - for example, increases in labour costs, as was the case in Westinghouse.271 As stated above, the majority of Westinghouse's clients were prepared to accept the increase in price (presumably because they found it reasonable). However, if our law were not to allow any discretionary powers in respect of price, it would leave all Westinghouse's contracts open to attack and possibly void.272 As pointed out by Laing,273 that would be "quite bizarre".

3.4 Final remarks on the rule and public policy

It appears that in most cases public policy would dictate that a discretion to determine the price should be enforced, provided that such a discretion is not unfettered and subject to an external objective standard or reasonableness. However, in cases where an unfair bargaining position is present, public policy may dictate otherwise. As stated above, public policy is context-sensitive and dependent on the facts of a particular case.274 Whether a term providing for the unilateral determination of the price would be contrary to public policy or not will depend on the facts of the case.275 In fact, the court may identify other factors that may be relevant to a public policy investigation in a specific case. However, it is submitted that at a minimum the considerations and factors discussed above should be taken into account when making such an assessment.

 

4 Conclusion

It has been shown that the rule that prohibits the unilateral determination of price should not be regarded as a manifestation of the requirement for certainty of price. Where a discretion to determine the price is subject to an external objective standard or reasonableness, this will result in the price being certain and consequently the contract of sale should be valid. This also seems to accord with the principle of contractual autonomy. Where an unequal bargaining relationship is present, further investigation is required because the term could possibly be regarded as contrary to public policy. This reasoning is reflected in recent developments in consumer law that have marked a departure from the traditional reverence reserved for contractual autonomy to a contractual order striving to protect consumers against unfair business practices (including unfair contract terms and prices).

 

Bibliography

Barnard J and Nagel C "Jordan v Farber (1352/09) [2009] ZANCHC 81 (15/12/2009)" 2010 (13)3 PELJ 449-463        [ Links ]

Beck A "'Void for vagueness': The layman's contract in court" 1985 SALJ 660673        [ Links ]

Bradfield G and Lehmann K (eds) Principles of the Law of Sale and Lease 2nd ed (Juta Cape Town 2010)        [ Links ]

Brand A "Geldigheid van huurkontrak" 1993 Codicillus 83-84        [ Links ]

Christie RH and Bradfield GB Christies the Law of Contract in South Africa 6th ed (LexisNexis Durban 2011)        [ Links ]

Cockrell A "Second-guessing the exercise of contractual power on rationality grounds" 1997 Acta Juridica 26-54        [ Links ]

Cornelius Interpretation Cornelius SJ Principles of the Interpretation of Contracts in South Africa 2nd ed (LexisNexis Durban 2007)        [ Links ]

Cornelius S "Discretionary clauses in contracts: The next episode in the ongoing saga" 2003 TSAR 388-390        [ Links ]

Davids J "Unilaterally imposed terms in contract" 1965 SALJ 108-114        [ Links ]

De Wet JC and Van Wyk AH Die Suid-Afrikaanse Kontraktereg en Handelsreg 5 ed (Butterworths Durban 1992)        [ Links ]

Du Bois F et al (eds) Wille's Principles of South African law 9th ed (Juta Cape Town 2007)        [ Links ]

Du Plessis HM Unilateral Determination of Price in Contracts of Sale Governed by the Consumer Protection Act 68 of 2008 (LLM dissertation UP 2012)        [ Links ]

Du Plessis HM "The unilateral determination of price in Roman law" 2012 Fundamina 15-31        [ Links ]

Fouché MA (ed) Legal Principles of Contracts and Commercial law 6th ed (LexisNexis Durban 2007)        [ Links ]

Hackwill GRJ (ed) Mackeurtan's Sale of Goods in South Africa 5th ed (Juta Cape Town 1984)        [ Links ]

Hawthorne L "The contractual requirement of certainty of price" 1992 THRHR 538-648        [ Links ]

Hutchison D and Pretorius CJ (eds) Kontraktereg in Suid-Afrika (Oxford University Press Cape Town 2010)        [ Links ]

Joubert DJ General Principles of the Law on Contract (Juta Cape Town 1987) Kerr Contract        [ Links ]

Kerr AJ The Principles of the Law of Contract 6th ed (Butterworths Durban 2002) Kerr Sale        [ Links ]

Kerr AJ The Law of Sale and Lease 3rd ed (LexisNexis Butterworths Durban 2004) Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ        [ Links ]

Kerr A and Glover GB "May essential provisions of a contract be determined by one of the parties alone?" 2000 SALJ 201-209        [ Links ]

Kruger M "The role of public policy in the law of contract, revisited" 2011 SALJ 712-740        [ Links ]

Laing MR Price Adaptation and the Requirement of Certainty with Specific Reference to the Contract of Sale (LLM dissertation US 1999)        [ Links ]

Lawack-Davids VA "A mortgagee's power to increase the interest rate: Finality at last?" 2001 Obiter 181-189        [ Links ]

Lubbe GF "Kontraktuele diskresies, potestatiewe voorwaardes en die bepaaldheidsvereiste" 1989 TSAR 159-176        [ Links ]

Lubbe GF "Bona fides, billikheid and die openbare belang in die Suid-Afrikaanse kontraktereg" 1990 Stell LR 7-25         [ Links ]

Lubbe GF "The Bill of Rights and contract law" 2004 SALJ 395-423        [ Links ]

McLennan JS "Unilateral determination of contractual performance: The interest-rate controversy solved - but what next?" 2000 SA Merc LJ 485-488        [ Links ]

Mofokeng N "At any rate: The discretion of banks to vary interest rates in mortgage bonds challenged" 1998 Juta's Business Law 55-58        [ Links ]

Mostert DF, Joubert DJ and Viljoen G Die Koopkontrak (Butterworths Durban 1972)        [ Links ]

Nagel CJ (ed) Commercial Law 4th ed (LexisNexis Durban 2011)        [ Links ]

Naudé T "Unfair contract terms legislation: The implications of why we need it for its formulation and application" 2006 Stell LR 361-385        [ Links ]

Naudé T "The consumer's 'right to fair, reasonable and just terms' under the new Consumer Protection Act in comparative perspective" 2009 SALJ 505-536        [ Links ]

Osode PC "Farewell to the contractual discretionary powers controversy in South African law: NBS Boland Bank v One Berg River Drive and others" 2000 Afr J Int'l & Comp L 170-176        [ Links ]

Otto JM "Kontraktuele bedinge wat eensydige rentekoersvasstellings deur banke magtig" 1998 TSAR 603-620        [ Links ]

Otto JM "Unilateral determination of interest rates by creditors: The Supreme Court of Appeal (almost) settles the matter" 2000 SALJ 1-8        [ Links ]

Roberts AA (ed) The Law of Contract in South Africa by Wessels JW Vol 1 2nd ed (Butterworths Durban 1951)        [ Links ]

Roberts AA (ed) The Law of Contract in South Africa by Wessels JW Vol 2 2nd ed (Butterworths Durban 1951)        [ Links ]

South African Law Commission Project 47 Final Report: Unreasonable Stipulations in Contracts and the Rectification of Contracts (The Commission Pretoria 1998)        [ Links ]

Schulze H "Purchase prices, contract of donation, and 'buildings form part of the land" 2003 Juta's Business Law 201-204        [ Links ]

Sharrock R Business Transaction Law 8th ed (Juta Cape Town 2011)        [ Links ]

Sutherland PJ "Ensuring contractual fairness in consumer contracts after Barkhuizen v Napier 2007 5 SA 323 (CC) - Part 1" 2008 Stell LR 390-413        [ Links ]

Van den Bergh R "The Roman tradition in the South African contract of sale" 2012 TSAR 53-74        [ Links ]

Van der Merwe et al Contract Van der Merwe S et al Contract: General Principles 3rd ed (Juta Cape Town 2007)        [ Links ]

Van Huyssteen LF, Van der Merwe SWJ and Maxwell CJ Contract Law in South Africa (Kluwer Law Alphen aan den Rijn 2010)        [ Links ]

Visser C et al (eds) South African Mercantile and Company Law by Gibson JTR 8th ed (Juta Cape Town 2005)        [ Links ]

Woker T "Why the need for consumer protection legislation? A look at some of the reasons behind the promulgation of the National Credit Act and the Consumer Protection Act" 2010 Obiter 217-231        [ Links ]

Zulman RH and Kairinos G (eds) Norman's Law of Purchase and Sale in South Africa 5th ed (LexisNexis Butterworths Durban 2005)        [ Links ]

Register of cases

ABSA Bank Ltd v Deeb 1999 2 SA 656 (N)

ABSA Bank Ltd v Lombard 2005 5 SA 350 (SCA)

Afrox Healthcare Ltd v Strydom 2002 6 SA 21 (SCA)

Aris Enterprises (Finance) (Pty) Ltd v Waterberg Koelkamers (Pty) Ltd 1977 2 SA 425 (A)

Barkhuizen v Napier 2007 5 SA 323 (CC)

Bellville-Inry (Edms) Bpk v Continental China (Pty) Ltd 1976 3 SA 583 (C)

Benlou Properties (Pty) Ltd v Vector Graphics (Pty) Ltd 1993 1 SA 179 (A)

Boland Bank Bpk v Steele 1994 1 SA 259 (T)

Breau Investments (Pty) Ltd v Maverick Trading 236 CC 2010 1 SA 367 (GNP)

Bredenkamp v Standard Bank of South Africa Ltd 2010 4 SA 468 (SCA)

Brisley v Drotsky 2002 4 SA 1 (SCA)

Bryer v Teabosa CC t/a Simon Chuter Properties 1993 1 SA 128 (C)

Burroughs Machines Ltd v Chenille Corporation of SA (Pty) Ltd 1964 1 SA 669 (W)

Coronel v Kaufman 1920 TPD 207

Dawidowitz v Van Drimmelen 1913 TPD 672

Deary v Deputy Commissioner of Inland Revenue 1920 CPD 541

Dharumpal Transport (Pty) Ltd v Dharumpal 1956 1 SA 700 (A)

Dicknnson & Fisher v Arndt & Cohn 1909 30 NLR 172

Dublin v Diner 1964 1 SA 799 (D)

Engen Petroleum Ltd v Kommandonek (Pty) Ltd 2001 2 SA 170 (W)

Erasmus v Senwes Ltd 2006 3 SA 529 (T)

Everfresh Market Virginia (Pty) Ltd v Shoprite Checkers (Pty) Ltd 2012 1 SA 256 (CC)

FW Knowles (Pty) Ltd v Cash-Inn (Pty) Ltd 1986 4 SA 641 (C)

Genac Properties JHB (Pty) Ltd v NBC Administrators CC (previously NBC Administrators (Pty) Ltd) 1992 1 SA 566 (A)

Gillig v Sonnenberg 1953 4 SA 675 (T) Hattingh v Van Rensburg 1964 1 SA 578 (T)

Herbert Porter & Co Ltd v Johannesburg Stock Exchange 1974 4 SA 781 (W)

H Merks & Co (Pty) Ltd v The B-M Group (Pty) Ltd 1996 2 SA 225 (A)

Hoffman and Carvalho v Minister of Agriculture 1947 2 SA 855 (T)

Holmes v Goodall & Williams, Ltd 1936 CPD 35

Hurwitz v Table Bay Engineering (Pty) Ltd 1994 3 SA 449 (C)

Investec Bank (Pty) Ltd v GVN Properties CC 1999 3 SA 490 (W)

Johnston v Leal 1980 3 SA 927 (A)

Joosub Investments (Pty) Ltd v Maritime & General Insurance Co Ltd 1990 3 SA 373 (C)

Jordan v Farber [2010] JOL 24810 (NCB)

Juglal v Shoprtte Checkers (Pty) Ltd t/a OK Franchise Division 2004 5 SA 248 (SCA)

Koumantarakis Group CC v Mystic River Investment 45 (Pty) Ltd 2007 6 SA 404 (D)

Lambons (Edms) Bpk v BMW (Suid-Afrika) (Edms) Bpk 1997 4 SA 141 (SCA)

Lichtheim v Stern 1910 WLD 284

Lobo Properties (Pty) Ltd v Express Lift Co (SA) (Pty) Ltd 1961 1 SA 704 (C)

Machanick v Simon 1920 CPD 333

Margate Estates Limited v Moore 1943 TPD 54

Meyer v Kirner 1974 4 SA 90 (N)

Moe Bros Appellants v White Respondent 1925 AD 71

Murray & Roberts Construction Ltd v Finat Properties (Pty) Ltd 1991 1 SA 508 (A)

NBS Bank and Investec Bank (Pty) Ltd v GVN Properties CC 1999 3 SA 490 (W)

NBS Bank Ltd v Badenhorst-Schnetler Bedryfsdienste BK 1998 3 SA 729 (W)

NBS Boland Bank Ltd v One Berg River Drive CC; Deeb v ABSA Bank Ltd; Friedman v Standard Bank of SA Ltd 1999 4 SA 928 (SCA) Nedbank Ltd v Capttal Refrigerated Truck Bodies (Pty) Ltd 1988 4 SA 73 (N)

Nedcor Bank Ltd v SDR Investment Holdings Co (Pty) Ltd 2008 3 SA 544 (SCA)

Odensdaalsrust Municipality v New Nigel Estate Gold Mining Co Ltd 1948 2 SA 656 (O)

Pareto Ltd v Mythos Leather Manufacturing (Pty) Ltd 2000 3 SA 999 (W)

Patel v Adam 1977 2 SA 653 (A)

Proud Investments (Pty) Ltd v Lanchem International (Pty) Ltd 1991 3 SA 738 (A)

Remini v Basson 1993 3 SA 204 (N)

Reymond v Abdulnabi 1985 3 SA 348 (W)

Sadie v Annandale 1992 2 SA 240 (O)

Sasfin (Pty) Ltd v Beukes 1989 1 SA 1 (A)

Shell SA (Pty) Ltd v Corbitt 1986 4 SA 523 (C)

Soteriou v Retco Poyntons (Pty) Ltd 1985 2 SA 922 (A)

Southern Life Association Ltd v Miller 2005 2 All SA 371 (SCA)

Standard Bank of SA Ltd v Friedman 1999 2 SA 456 (C)

Stead v Conradie 1995 2 SA 111 (A)

Steyn v Lomlin (Edms) Bpk 1980 1 SA 167 (O)

Theron v Joynt 1951 1 SA 498 (A)

Van Heerden v Basson 1998 1 SA 715 (T)

Unilever South Africa Ice Cream (Pty) Ltd (known as Ola South Africa (Pty) Ltd) v Jepson 2008 2 SA 456 (C)

Westinghouse Brake & Equipment (Pty) Ltd v Bigger Engineering (Pty) Ltd 1986 2 SA 555 (A)

Williams and Taylor v Hitchcock 1915 WLD 51

Register of legislation

Constitution of the Republic of South Africa, 1996

Consumer Protection Act 68 of 2008

Electronic Communications and Transactions Act 25 of 2002

Register of government publications

GN R293 in GG 34180 of 1 April 2011 (Consumer Protection Act Regulations)

List of abbreviations

Afr J Int'l & Comp L African Journal of International and Comparative Law

CPA Consumer Protection Act

PELJ Potchefstroom Electronic Law Journal

SALC South African Law Commission

SALJ South African Law Journal

SA Merc LJ South African Mercantile Law Journal

Stell LR Stellenbosch Law Review

THRHR Tydskrif vir die Hedendaagse Romeins-Hollandse Reg

TSAR Tydskrif vir Suid-Afrikaanse Reg

 

 

1 Westnnghouse Brake & Equipment (Pty) Ltd v Bilger Engineering (Pty) Ltd 1986 2 SA 555 (A) 574 (hereafter Westnnghouse).
2 See eg Burroughs Machines Ltd v Chenille Corporation of SA (Pty) Ltd 1964 1 SA 669 (W) 670 (hereafter Burroughs); Steyn v Lomlin (Edms) Bpk 1980 1 SA 167 (O) 170; Westnnghouse 574; Murray & Roberts Construction Ltd v Finat Properties (Pty) Ltd 1991 1 SA 508 (A) 514-515 (hereafter Murray & Roberts).
3 Otto 1998 TSAR 604; Lubbe 1989 TSAR 160; Kerr Sale 60-65; Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 638; Mofokeng 1998 Juta's Business Law 55-56; Osode 2000 Afr J Int'l & Comp L 170-171.
4 Benlou Properties (Pty) Ltd v Vector Graphics (Pty) Ltd 1993 1 SA 179 (A) 186 (hereafter Benlou Properties). These remarks were made obiter in respect of the price in a contract of sale as the case dealt with a lease agreement.
5 Cornelius 2003 TSAR 389; Lawack-Davids 2001 Obiter 181. For more background information on the reasons for the steep increase in interest rates see Otto 1998 TSAR 616.
6 NBS Boland Bank Ltd v One Berg River Drive CC; Deeb v ABSA Bank Ltd; Friedman v Standard Bank of SA Ltd 1999 4 SA 928 (SCA) (hereafter NBS Boland Bank).
7 NBS Boland Bank para 24.
8 NBS Boland Bank para 24. Subsequently, in Erasmus v Senwes Ltd 2006 3 SA 529 (T) 538 (hereafter Erasmus), the court extended the last requirement to include a discretion that relates to a party's own performance.
9 NBS Boland Bank para 25.
10 NBS Boland Bank paras 9, 10, 16 and 32.
11 NBS Boland Bank para 16.
12 NBS Boland Bank para 28.
13 NBS Boland Bank paras 16 and 32. See also Kerr Sale 55.
14 Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 19; Cornelius Interpretation 148; Du Bois et al Wille's Principles of SA Law 891; Zulman and Kairinos Norman's Purchase and Sale 2; Osode 2000 Afr J Int'l & Comp L 175-176.
15 Van der Merwe et al Contract 9.
16 De Wet and Van Wyk Kontraktereg 93; Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 218; Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 638; Lubbe 1989 TSAR 159; Otto 1998 TSAR 603; Otto 2000 SALJ 1.
17 Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 17; Du Bois et al Wllle's Principles of SA Law 754; Van der Merwe et al Contract 221; Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 638.
18 Du Bois et al Wllle's Principles of SA Law 754.
19 De Wet and Van Wyk Kontraktereg 93.
20 Dawidowitz v Van Drimmelen 1913 TPD 672 675 (hereafter Dawddowitz); Meyer v Kirner 1974 4 SA 90 (N) 97 (hereafter Meyer). See also Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 11; Fouché Contracts 136; Hackwill Mackeurtan's Sale 14; Mostert, Joubert and Viljoen Koopkontrak 6; Zulman and Kairinos Norman's Purchase and Sale 2; Schulze 2003 Juta's Business Law 201.
21 Coronel v Kaufman 1920 TPD 207 209; Deary v Deputy Commissioner of Inland Revenue 1920 CPD 541 552; Margate Estates Limited v Moore 1943 TPD 54 59; Hattingh v Van Rensburg 1964 1 SA 578 (T) 582; Meyer 97; Aris Enterprises (Finance) (Pty) Ltd v Waterberg Koekkamers (Pty) Ltd 1977 2 SA 425 (A) 434; Patel v Adam 1977 2 SA 653 (A) 665 (hereafter Patel); Johnston v Leal 1980 3 SA 927 (A) 938; Reymond v Abdulnabi 1985 3 SA 348 (W) 349. See also Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 18; Fouché Contracts 137; Visser et al Gibson's Mercantile Law 114; Hackwill Mackeurtan's Sale 14; Roberts Wessels' Contract Vol 2 1093; Nagel Commercial Law 197; Van den Bergh 2012 TSAR 63.
22 Burroughs 670.
23 Westinghouse 574; Shell SA (Pty) Ltd v Corbitt 1986 4 SA 523 (C) 526 (hereafter Shell); Genac Properties JHB (Pty) Ltd v NBC Administrators CC (previously NBC Administrators (Pty) Ltd) 1992 1 SA 566 (A) 576-577 (hereafter Genac Properties); H Merks & Co (Pty) Ltd v The B-M Group (Pty) Ltd 1996 2 SA 225 (A) 233 (hereafter H Merks); Lambons (Edms) Bpk v BMW (Suid-Afrika) (Edms) Bpk 1997 4 SA 141 (SCA) 158; Pareto Ltd v Mythos Leather Manufacturing (Pty) Ltd 2000 3 SA 999 (W) para 9 (hereafter Pareto).
24 This is in accordance with the principle certum est quod certum reddi potest ("something is certain if it can be made certain") found in D 12 1 6 and D 45 1 74 (Mostert, Joubert and Viljoen Koopkontrak 10; Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 640). For examples of acceptable external standards see Du Bois et al Wille's Principles of SA Law 891; Hackwill Mackeurtan's Sale 15; Joubert Contract 179-180; Kerr Sale 33-34; Mostert, Joubert and Viljoen Koopkontrak 12; Van der Merwe et al Contract 227; Zulman and Kairinos Norman's Purchase and Sale 43; Nagel Commercial Law 198; Sharrock Business Law 272.
25 Van der Merwe et al Contract 223. As pointed out by Laing Price 18, although an objective standard is required, the courts have given different meanings to what would be considered objective. See further para 0 below.
26 There are differing opinions on whether these two requirements (an external standard and no further recourse to the parties) should be tested independently or not (Laing Price Adaptation 19). See further para 0 below.
27 See further para 0 below.
28 Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 638; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 203; Otto 1998 TSAR 604; Schulze 2003 Juta's Business Law 201.
29 Kerr Sale 64; Kerr Contract 132; Davids 1965 SALJ 110.
30 Machanick v Simon 1920 CPD 333 (hereafter Machanick).
31 Machanick 336. For a detailed discussion on the Roman law sources see Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 15-31.
32 Machanick 333.
33 Machanick 333.
34 See eg Dharumpal Transport (Pty) Ltd v Dharumpal 1956 1 SA 700 (A) 706-707 (hereafter Dharumpal) and Burroughs 670.
35 Kerr Sale 64.
36 Laing Price Adaptation 20. Laing refers to the following extract in Odensdaalsrust Municipality v New Nigel Estate Gold Mining Co Ltd 1948 2 SA 656 (O) 665: "The contract itself must place the subject-matter of the transaction, the price and the fact of consensus out of range of the clash of the will of the parties."
37 Laing Price Adaptation 59, 153-154.
38 Benlou Properties 185. The court's comment was made in light of the fact that the determination of the purchase price or rent by a third party is acceptable in our law (Pareto para 9).
39 NBS Boland Bank para 32. This remark was made obiter. See also Lubbe 1989 TSAR 173; Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 223.
40 Genac Properties 579.
41 Engen Petroleum Ltd v Kommandonek (Pty) Ltd 2001 2 SA 170 (W) 173-174 (hereafter Engen Petroleum).
42 Engen Petroleum 174. These remarks were made obiter as the court held that the contract expressly limited the discretion to an objectively ascertainable discretion (at 173).
43 See also Cornelius 2003 TSAR 390.
44 Dawidowttz 672; Dharumpal 707. See also Mostert, Joubert and Viljoen Koopkontrak 11. A pure potestative condition may be described as a condition "which depends entirely upon the will of the promisor" (Roberts Wessels' Contract Vol 1 406 para 1313). It is also known as a condition si voluero ("if I wish") and "refers to the situation where the existence of the contract is made dependent on the will of one of the parties" (Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 21).
45 Dawidowttz 672.
46 Laing Price Adaptation 131 n 612. Therefore, the court's remarks regarding unilateral determinations of price were made obiter (Lubbe 1989 TSAR 163; Laing Price Adaptation 132 n 616).
47 Dawidowttz 674.
48 Dawidowitz 675. Strangely, in Wllliams and Taylor v Hitchcock 1915 WLD 51 it would seem that Wessels changed his mind. This seems to be true even though Wessels specifically distinguished this case from the case in Dawidowitz 53-54. The parties agreed that the purchaser would not be called upon to pay the purchase price "until such time as he is in a financial position to do so" (at 52). These facts are almost identical to the facts in Dawidowttz. Wessels J held that the contract was not void for vagueness and did not depend entirely on the will of one of the parties (at 54). See also Beck 1985 SALJ 666.
49 Laing Price Adaptation 131 n 612.
50 Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 20-23. See also Laing Price Adaptation 131 n 612; Van der Merwe et al Contract 236, 243 n 146.
51 Theron v Joynt 1951 1 SA 498 (A) 506. This remark was also obiter (see Lubbe 1989 TSAR 164 n 30).
52 Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 204 argues that the word has been used in translations of Van der Keessel's work to refer to a discretion to determine the price.
53 Benlou Properties 186.
54 NBS Boland Bank paras 22-23. See further Lubbe 1989 TSAR 176; Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 22.
55 Erasmus 537. See also Van der Merwe et al Contract 243 n 146.
56 Laing Price Adaptation 122.
57 Laing Price Adaptation 122. See also Van der Merwe et al Contract 235; Lubbe 1989 TSAR 171.
58 NBS Bolank Bank para 9.
59 Kerr Sale 59; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 208. See further Du Plessis Unllateral Determination of Price 39-48. There is also no reference to vagueness in the Roman law (see Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 15-30 and Kerr Sale 58-59).
60 Dharumpal 70; Westinghouse 574; Shell 525-526; Murray & Roberts 514; Boland Bank Bpk v Steele 1994 1 SA 259 (T) 274 (hereafter Boland Bank); NBS Bank Ltd v Badenhorst-Schnetler Bedryfsdienste BK 1998 3 SA 729 (W) 736 (hereafter NBS Bank). Other cases that do not refer to Dawidowitz directly refer to one of the cases listed above. See for example, H Merks 233 referring to Westinghouse.
61 Dawidowitz 675. See the full extract from this judgment in para 0 above.
62 See para 0 above.
63 Kerr Sale 57 where he refers to the dictionary meaning of "vague" and "vagueness".
64 Kerr Sale 57.
65 Kerr Sale 65; Sharrock Business Law 89.
66 Kerr Contract 133; Laing Price Adaptation 65.
67 Kerr Sale 65; Laing Price Adaptation 65.
68 Van der Merwe et al Contract 235.
69 Kerr Sale 57-58. See para 0 above.
70 See para 0 below.
71 See para 0 below.
72 Kerr Sale 71.
73 Kerr Sale 71. However, these "concerns" have not resulted in third-party determinations not being recognised in South African law. See para 0 below in respect of how this problem is dealt with in third-party price determinations.
74 Kerr Sale 71. However, Kerr concedes that his real reason for distinguishing the two instances from each other is because the unilateral determination of price was not allowed in Roman law, while third-party determinations were. This is not the case and there are various interpretations in Roman law that would allow for one of the parties to determine the price, including that such a discretion would have to be exercised arbitrio boni viri (Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 24-29). See also Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 208; Beck 1985 SALJ 662.
75 Kerr Sale 71.
76 H Merks 230.
77 See eg Bellville-Inry (Edms) Bpk v Continental China (Pty) Ltd 1976 3 SA 583 (C) 592 (hereafter Bellville-inry).
78 Bellville-inry 592. See para 0 below.
79 Laing Price Adaptation 152 referring to Benlou Properties 187-188.
80 For a detailed discussion on the interpretation of D 18 1 35 1 see Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 15-31. See also Du Plessis Unilateral Determination of Price ch 2.
81 Benlou Properties 186. However, the court stated that it was "bound to the views of our old authorities". See further Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 24-26.
82 NBS Boland Bank para 24.
83 Burroughs 670.
84 See para 0 above.
85 Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 640; Laing Price Adaptation 19. Contra Kerr who merely states that the price should be ascertainable without further reference to the parties (Kerr Sale 33).
86 Laing Price Adaptation 20; Van der Merwe et al Contract 227.
87 Laing Price Adaptation 20. See n 36 above.
88 Van der Merwe et al Contract 237.
89 Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 647.
90 Murray & Roberts 515. However, the court accepted that whether this method would refer to an objective and external standard or not would depend on the relationship between the contracting parties and the independence and competence of the third party who jointly with one of the parties would determine the price. However, Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 642 argues that the judgment has indicative (but not authoritative) value because the court dealt with the specific facts only and refused to lay down a general rule.
91 Stead v Conradie 1995 2 SA 111 (A) 123 (hereafter Stead).
92 Stead 123.
93 Stead 123.
94 Stead 123.
95 Proud Investments (Pty) Ltd v Lanchem International (Pty) Ltd 1991 3 SA 738 (A) 747 (hereafter Proud In vestments).
96 Proud Investments 750.
97 Proud In vestments 747.
98 Proud In vestments 747.
99 Proud In vestments 747.
100 Proud Investments 751. Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 643-644 criticises the judgment as not setting an objective standard because the auditors were appointed by the landlord and therefore acting as his agent. However, Laing Price Adaptation 137 n 643 argues that as the contract referred to reasonable costs it already constituted an objective standard and the auditors were obliged to act reasonably.
101 Genac Properties 579.
102 Genac Properties 579.
103 Benlou Properties 182. See also Brand 1993 Codicillus 83.
104 Benlou Properties 184. First, it was limited to a certain percentage (74,4%) of the increased expenditure. Secondly, the expenditure actually had to be incurred and, finally, only increases in expenses applicable at the date of commencement of the negotiations would be taken into account. Therefore no new expenses could be claimed from the tenant.
105 Engen Petroleum 173.
106 Engen Petroleum 173-174.
107 Laing Price Adaptation 138, where the author states that the court regards "reasonableness as a concept quite capable of objective ascertainment".
108 Laing Price Adaptation 154 argues that this is a manifestation of the principle of good faith that underlies the South African law of contract.
109 See para 0 above.
110 NBS Boland Bank para 25. Referred to with approval in Juglal v Shoprite Checkers (Pty) Ltd t/a OK Franchise Division 2004 5 SA 248 (SCA) 261 (hereafter Juglal); Koumantarakis Group CC v Mystic River Investment 45 (Pty) Ltd 2007 6 SA 404 (D) para 37 (hereafter Koumantarakis Group). Prior to the decision in NBS Boland Bank, the court in Benlou Properties held that reasonableness would be implied by law as the standard where one of the parties was granted a discretion.
111 Moe Bros Appellants v White Respondent 1925 AD 71 77; Holmes v Goodall & Williams, Ltd 1936 CPD 35 40; Dharumpal 707; Herbert Porter & Co Ltd v Johannesburg Stock Exchange 1974 4 SA 781 (W) 789 (hereafter Herbert Porter); Bellville-inry 592; Remini v Basson 1993 3 SA 204 (N) 210 (hereafter Remini). Reference can also be made to Machanick 340-341 and Joosub Investments (Pty) Ltd v Maritime & General Insurance Co Ltd 1990 3 SA 373 (C) 383 (hereafter Joosub Investments).
112 NBS Boland Bank paras 25-26.
113 See Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 26-27.
114 See Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 26-27.
115 See Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 26-27.
116 See Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 26-27.
117 NBS Boland Bank para 32.
118 Dickinson & Fisher v Arndt & Cohn 1909 30 NLR 172 (hereafter Dickinson & Fisher); Laing Price Adaptation 131.
119 Dickinson & Fisher 175.
120 Dickinson & Fisher 183.
121 Dicknnson & Fisher 187.
122 Dicknnson & Fisher 183.
123 Lichtheim v Stern 1910 WLD 284-285 (hereafter Lichtheim).
124 Lichtheim 286.
125 Lichtheim 284.
126 Lichtheim 288.
127 Lichtheim 288. See also Lubbe 1989 TSAR 164-165 for his discussion of this case.
128 Benlou Properties 186; Engen Petroleum 174-175.
129 Cockrell 1997 Acta Juridica 34 and the cases mentioned in n 40.
130 This would accord with the views of the South African writers. Cornelius 2003 TSAR 390 proposed that the discretion should be exercised in good faith and reasonably. He argued that good faith would refer to the purpose for the exercise of the discretion and reasonability would refer "to the various socio-economic factors that influence the sustainability of a particular performance". McLennan 2000 SA Merc LJ 487 also referred to the differences between good faith and reasonableness and argued that "the test should expressly include objectivity: the determination must be exercised fairly and reasonably". Otto also refers to the test of reasonableness (Otto 2000 SALJ 5).
131 Juglal para 26.
132 Unieever South Africa Ice Cream (Pty) Ltd (known as Ola South Africa (Pty) Ltd) v Jepson 2008 2 SA 456 (C) 461; Remini 210; Joosub Investments 383; F W Knowees (Pty) Ltd v Cash-Inn (Pty) Ltd 1986 4 SA 641 (C) 650 (hereafter F W Knowles); Herbert Porter 789. This is why the court has been willing to regard a discretion in respect of the price or rent subject to some measure of reasonableness as a reference to an objective standard (cf para 0 above).
133 Erasmus 538. See also Cockrell 1997 Acta Juridica 32.
134 Nedcor Bank Ltd v SDR Investment Hoddings Co (Pty) Ltd 2008 3 SA 544 (SCA) para 8.
135 Erasmus 538.
136 Otto 2000 SALJ 5. In Visser et al Gibson's Mercantlle Law 114 the author states the following: "Terms to be bound by what is 'fair and reasonable' are well known throughout the law of contract ... [a]nd the courts have to, and do assess what is reasonable in all manner of contexts."
137 Koumantarakis Group para 50. See also Bryer v Teabosa CC t/a Simon Chuter Properties 1993 1 SA 128 (C) 137 (hereafter Bryer).
138 Koumantarakis Group para 39.
139 Koumantarakis Group para 49; F W Knowles 649-650. A good example is where the contract already prescribes certain criteria for the exercise of the discretion. See para 0 above.
140 F W Knowles 650; Erasmus 540. Van der Merwe et al Contract 240 proposes that consideration must be given to the interests of the party bound by the discretion in such a way as not to "reduce what was intended as a mutually beneficial exchange of performances to a transaction serving the interests of one party only".
141 Koumantarakis Group para 42.
142 Lobo Properties (Pty) Ltd v Express Lift Co (SA) (Pty) Ltd 1961 1 SA 704 (C) 708.
143 Otto 2000 SALJ 5-7.
144 Otto 2000 SALJ 6 referring to NBS Bank and Investec Bank (Pty) Ltd v GVN Properties CC 1999 3 SA 490 (W) (hereafter Investec Bank).
145 Otto 2000 SALJ 7 referring to Nedbank Ltd v Capital Refrigerated Truck Bodies (Pty) Ltd 1988 4 SA 73 (N). Otto provides possible examples in respect of the classes of customer, namely "individual and corporate customers" and "new and longstanding customers".
146 Otto 2000 SALJ 7 referring to Boland Bank and ABSA Bank Ltd v Deeb 1999 2 SA 656 (N).
147 Otto 2000 SALJ 7 referring to Standard Bank of SA Ltd v Friedman 1999 2 SA 456 (C) (hereafter Standard Bank).
148 Otto 2000 SALJ 7 referring to Standard Bank.
149 NBS Boland Bank para 29.
150 NBS Boland Bank para 29. See also Zulman and Kairinos Norman's Purchase and Sale 45.
151 Laing Price Adaptation 155.
152 Laing Price Adaptation 155.
153 Laing Price Adaptation 155.
154 Laing Price Adaptation 20; Hackwill Mackeurtan's Sale 16; Kerr Sale 37; Sharrock Business Law 272.
155 Kerr Sale 38.
156 See para 0 above.
157 Dublin v Diner 1964 1 SA 799 (D) 802 (hereafter Dublin); Van Heerden v Basson 1998 1 SA 715 (T) 718 (hereafter Van Heerden). See also Kerr Sale 39; Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 20.
158 Gillig v Sonnenberg 1953 4 SA 675 (T) 683 (hereafter Gillig); Dublin 804-805. This is based on the assumption that the parties "did not intend an arbitrary but a just estimation tanquam boni viri (Machanick 339). See also Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 20; Kerr Sale 39.
159 Sharrock Business Law 272; Kerr Sale 39.
160 Hurwitz v Table Bay Engineering (Pty) Ltd 1994 3 SA 449 (C) 456 (hereafter Hurwitz).
161 Nagel Commercial Law 198.
162 Kerr Sale 39 and 51; Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 20.
163 Gillig 683; Dubin 805; Hurwitz 459; Van Heerden 720; See also Bradfield and Lehmann Sale and Lease 20; Nagel Commercial Law 198; Sharrock Business Law 272.
164 For a more detailed discussion of this issue see Kerr Sale 39-55 and Laing Price Adaptation 38-47.
165 Hurwitz 459.
166 Van Heerden 720. Referred to with approval in Breau Investments (Pty) Ltd v Maverick Trading 236 CC 2010 1 SA 367 (GNP) paras 17-19. In this case the court confirmed that one of the parties may also exercise the right to cancel after litigation has commenced.
167 Kerr Sale 49-50.
168 Kerr Sale 50-51.
169 NBS Boland Bank para 22. Specifically, the court referred to D 45 1 17, D 45 1 46 3 and D 45 1 108 1. See further Du Plessis 2012 Fundamina 22-23.
170 NBS Boland Bank para 23.
171 NBS Boland Bank paras 24-25.
172 Erasmus 537-538. The court's reasons were that all contracts are subject to the principle of good faith and that parties should be held bound to their contracts. See also Van der Merwe et al Contract 239.
173 Erasmus 538.
174 Joubert Contract 62 and the authorities listed in n 35; Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 277; Otto 1998 TSAR 603; Otto 2000 SALJ 3.
175 Cornelius Interpretation 126.
176 Hoffman and Carvalho v Minister of Agricutture 1947 2 SA 855 (T) 860. Referred to with approval in Sadie v Annandale 1992 2 SA 240 (O) 244. See also Du Bois et al Wille's Principles of SA Law 755.
177 Soteriou v Retco Poyntons (Pty) Ltd 1985 2 SA 922 (A) 931; Genac Properties 579; Engen Petroleum 175. See also Lubbe 1989 TSAR 164, where he criticises the decisions in Burroughs and Patel.
178 Benlou Properties 187. See further para 0 below.
179 See para 0 above.
180 Kerr Sale 64.
181 See eg Genac Properties 579 and Boland Bank 276.
182 See eg Hackwill Mackeurtan's Sale 18-19 dealing with a contract of sale "at a reasonable price".
183 Burroughs 675.
184 Murray & Roberts 514-515.
185 Murray & Roberts 515.
186 Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 235.
187 Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 641.
188 Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 235.
189 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 183.
190 Sasfin (Pty) Ltd v Beukes 1989 1 SA 1 (A) 7 (hereafter Sasfin); Jordan v Farber [2010] JOL 24810 (NCB) para 12 (hereafter Jordan); Bredenkamp v Standard Bank of South Africa Ltd 2010 4 SA 468 (SCA) para 38 (hereafter Bredenkamp). See also Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 183.
191 Sasfin 8. See also Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 127.
192 Barkhuizen v Napier 2007 5 SA 323 (CC) para 28 (hereafter Barkhuizen).
193 Bredenkamp para 38; Sasfin 8. See also Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 127 and 200; Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 185; Kruger 2011 SALJ 713.
194 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 185; Christie and Bradfield Contract 360; Kruger 2011 SALJ 715.
195 Christie and Bradfield Contract 360-361; Kruger 2011 SALJ 733.
196 Van der Merwe et al Contract 199.
197 Bredenkamp para 38. See also Van der Merwe et al Contract 199; Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 186.
198 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 185.
199 The values are dignity, equality and freedom (Barkhuizen para 28). See further Bredenkamp para 39 where the court stated that "[t]he common law derives its force from the Constitution and is only 'valid' to the extent that it complies or is congruent with the Constitution".
200 Barkhuizen para 30 where the court stated as follows: "The proper approach to the constitutional challenge to contractual terms is to determine whether the term challenged is contrary to public policy as evidenced by constitutional values, in particular, those found in the Bill of Rights. This approach leaves space for the doctrine of pacta sunt servanda to operate, but at the same time allows courts to decline to enforce contractual terms that are in conflict with constitutional values even though the parties may have consented to them." See Everfresh Market Virginia (Pty) Ltd v Shoprite Checkers (Pty) Ltd 2012 1 SA 256 (CC) para 22 where the court stated that "issues of public policy in turn cannot be considered without reference to section 39(2) [of the Constitution]". See also Bredenkamp para 39; Jordan para 12-13; Brisley v Drotsky 2002 4 SA 1 (SCA) 34 (hereafter Brisley). See further Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 183, 185; Sutherland 2008 Stell LR 407; Christie and Bradfield Contract 361.
201 Sasfin 9; Brisley 35-36; Afrox Healthcare Ltd v Strydom 2002 6 SA 21 (SCA) para 8 (hereafter Afrox Healthcare); Juglal para 12. See also Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 185; Christie and Bradfield Contract 360.
202 Juglal para 12. See also Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 185.
203 Sasfin 9. See also Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 185. The same principle applies in respect of the enforcement of a contractual term. In Bredenkamp the court stated that it does not believe "that the enforcement of a valid contractual term must be fair and reasonable, even if no public policy consideration found in the Constitution or elsewhere is implicated" (para 50) and "that fairness is not a freestanding requirement for the exercise of a contractual right" (para 53).
204 Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 200-204; Van der Merwe et al Contract 200-201.
205 Sasfin 9. Also referred to as the maxim pacta sunt servanda.
206 Benlou Properties 187.
207 Erasmus 538.
208 Laing Price Adaptation 152.
209 Laing Price Adaptation 153.
210 Barkhuizen para 57; Afrox Healthcare para 23. See also Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 187.
211 Barkhuizen para 15. See also Barnard and Nagel 2010 PELJ 456.
212 Brisley 34-36. See also Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 57 n 8; Barnard and Nagel 2010 PELJ 456.
213 Benlou Properties 186; Erasmus 538.
214 Benlou Properties 186.
215 Erasmus 538.
216 Van der Merwe et al Contract 199; Lawack-Davids 2001 Obiter 188.
217 Van der Merwe et al Contract 199. See also the discussion of the role of good faith as a policy consideration in Lubbe 2004 SALJ 411-413.
218 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 193-194; Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 130.
219 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 193. This seems to accord with Lubbe's view that good faith, in the context of public policy, should not only encompass honesty but also require that a party's pursuit of his own interest "must be tempered by a reasonable measure of concern" for the other party's interest (Lubbe 1990 Stell LR 20 as quoted by Naudé 2009 SALJ 518).
220 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 193.
221 Dicknnson & Fisher 79; Sasfin 9. See also Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 127.
222 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 194.
223 Sasfin 10. See also Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 195; Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 129.
224 Sasfin 13-14. See also Van der Merwe et al Contract 219; Van Huyssteen, Van der Merwe and Maxwell Contract 129.
225 See para 0 below.
226 Kerr Sale 66.
227 Kerr Sale 66. In NBS Boland Bank para 30 the court questioned whether such discretions would be invalid (as contrary to public policy) or valid but assailable if not exercised in good faith. As pointed out by Van der Merwe et al Contract 242, what is meant by an unfettered discretion is not clear and therefore it is difficult to determine whether the discretion would be regarded as valid or not. They submit that this will have to be determined with reference to the specific facts of the case with special consideration given to the possibility of abuse of power by the party exercising the discretion.
228 Laing Price Adaptation 154 argues that the willingness of the court to imply a term of reasonableness in contractual discretions is a manifestation of the principle of good faith. As good faith informs public policy, the willingness of the court to imply a term of reasonableness can also be found in policy considerations.
229 See para 0 above.
230 Kerr Sale 72; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 207.
231 FW Knowles 650.
232 FW Knowles 650.
233 Bryer 134; Southern Life Association Ltd v Miller 2005 2 All SA 371 (SCA) 137; Koumantarakis Group para 38.
234 ABSA Bank Ltd v Lombard 2005 5 SA 350 (SCA) (hereafter ABSA Bank)
235 ABSA Bank 353-354.
236 ABSA Bank 354.
237 See para 0 above. However, this may still impose problems that should be addressed in consumer contracts. See further Du Plessis Unilateral Determination of Price 113-114.
238 If the discretion refers to a reasonable discretion, the courts regard such a discretion as referring to an objective standard. See paras 0 and 0 above.
239 Kerr Sale 66.
240 Kerr Sale 66; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 207.
241 Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 187.
242 Barkhuizen para 57. See also Hutchison and Pretorius Kontraktereg 187.
243 Laing Price Adaptation 124; Otto 1998 TSAR 620; Woker 2010 Obiter 218. See also Investec Bank 495, referring to Standard Bank 468-469.
244 Kerr Sale 72; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 207; See also Woker 2010 Obiter 230 discussing this issue in the context of consumer contracts.
245 Kerr Sale 72; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 207.
246 Kerr Sale 72; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 207; See also Woker 2010 Obtter 230 and Naudé 2006 Stell LR 380, 384 discussing this issue in the context of consumer contracts.
247 Kerr Sale 72; Kerr and Glover 2000 SALJ 207.
248 Afrox Healthcare para 12. Jordan is a good example, where the court looked at an unequal bargaining relationship in the context of various other considerations. See also Barnard and Nagel 2010 PELJ 457.
249 Kerr Sale 72, where Kerr refers to the 1998 Final Report of the South African Law Commission Project 47 on "Unreasonable stipulations in contracts and the rectification of contracts" (SALC Project 47).
250 Section 23 does not apply to a transaction where an estimate was given for repair and maintenance services in terms of s 15 of the CPA or a transaction governed by s 43 of the E/ectronlc Communications and Transactions Act 25 of 2002. S 23(4) provides a further exception: "A retailer is not required to display for any goods that are displayed predominantly as a form of advertisement of the supplier, or of goods or services, in an area within the supplier's premises to which the public does not ordinarily have access." The meaning of s 23(4) is unclear (see Du Plessis "Price discretions and the consumer's right to disclosure and information in terms of the Consumer Protection Act 68 of 2008" to be published in 2013 THRHR).
251 There are a few exceptions to this rule (see s 23(7)-(10 of the CPA).
252 Section 23(6)(b) of the CPA.
253 Section 48(2)(a) of the CPA provides that a term is unfair, unreasonable or unjust if it is excessively one-sided in favour of any person other than a consumer. S 48(2)(b) states that if a term of an agreement is so adverse to the consumer as to be inequitable, the term will be unfair, unreasonable or unjust.
254 Reference can also be made to the presumed unfair terms contained in reg 44(3) of the regulations in terms of s 120(1)(d) of the CPA (Consumer Protection Act Regulations, GN R293 in GG 34180 of 1 April 2011). Reg 44(1) provides that these terms would be applicable to consumer contracts between a supplier operating on a for-profit basis and acting wholly or mainly for purposes related to his or her business or profession and an individual consumer or individual consumers who entered into it for purposes wholly or mainly unrelated to his or her business or profession. Reg 44(3)(h) provides that a term is presumed unfair if it allows the supplier to increase the price agreed on when the agreement was concluded without the consumer having the right to terminate the agreement (subject to the exceptions listed in reg 44(4)(b)). Secondly, reg 44(3)(i) provides that a term is presumed unfair if it allows the supplier to alter the terms of the contract unilaterally. The same exceptions as in the first instance apply and a further exception is where the supplier has the right to amend the terms of an open-ended agreement unilaterally, provided the supplier informs the consumer of the amendment and the consumer has the right to dissolve the agreement immediately (reg 44(4)(c)(iv)).
255 A detailed discussion of these provisions is outside the scope of this article. For such a detailed discussion see Du Plessis Unilateral Determination of Price ch 4.
256 Van der Merwe et al Contract 236.
257 Laing Price Adaptation 124; Hawthorne 1992 THRHR 646-647.
258 Laing Price Adaptation 124.
259 Laing Price Adaptation 124. The clause read as follows: "It is not possible for Burroughs Machines Limited ... to quote a firm price for the new equipment offered in this order. We are informed by our factory that the price quoted as 'approximate' is not final and is subject to change at any time prior to delivery, to provide for possible changes in manufacturing costs, and fluctuations in the rate of exchange" (Burroughs 672).
260 Laing Price Adaptation 124.
261 Laing Price Adaptation 124.
262 Laing Price Adaptation 124.
263 This may make it more difficult for the buyer to prove that the seller exercised its discretion unreasonably. Laing Price Adaptation 124 argues that this would also allow for a greater possibility of abuse of this power by the seller (especially in standard form contracts) that would need to be addressed.
264 Laing Price Adaptation 125.
265 Laing Price Adaptation 125.
266 Laing Price Adaptation 125.
267 Laing Price Adaptation 125.
268 Laing Price Adaptation 125.
269 Westinghouse 574.
270 Westinghouse 574.
271 See for instance the escalation clause in Westinghouse 566.
272 Laing Price Adaptation 128.
273 Laing Price Adaptation 128.
274 See para 0 above.
275 Kruger 2011 SALJ 733.

Creative Commons License All the contents of this journal, except where otherwise noted, is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution License