SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.112 número3-4Academic freedom statement from the Academy Of Science Of South Africa (ASSAf) índice de autoresíndice de materiabúsqueda de artículos
Home Pagelista alfabética de revistas  

Servicios Personalizados

Articulo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • En proceso de indezaciónCitado por Google
  • En proceso de indezaciónSimilares en Google

Compartir


South African Journal of Science

versión On-line ISSN 1996-7489
versión impresa ISSN 0038-2353

S. Afr. j. sci. vol.112 no.3-4 Pretoria mar./abr. 2016

http://dx.doi.org/10.17159/sajs.2016/20150237 

RESEARCH ARTICLE

 

Trading on extinction: An open-access deterrence model for the South African abalone fishery

 

 

Douglas J. Crookes

Department of Economics, University of Pretoria, Pretoria, South Africa

Correspondence

 

 


ABSTRACT

South African rhinoceros (e.g. Diceros bicornis) and abalone (Haliotis midae) have in common that they both are harvested under open-access conditions, are high-value commodities and are traded illegally. The difference is that a legal market for abalone already exists. An open-access deterrence model was developed for South African abalone, using Table Mountain National Park as a case study. It was found that illegal poaching spiked following the closure of the recreational fishery. The resource custodian's objective is to maximise returns from confiscations. This study showed that a legal trade results in a 'trading on extinction' resource trap, with a race for profits, an increase in the probability of detection after a poaching event and the depletion of populations. In contrast with HS Gordon's seminal article (J Polit Econ 1954;62:124-142), profit maximisation does not automatically improve the sustainability of the resource. Under certain conditions (e.g. a legal trade with costly enforcement), profit maximisation may actually deplete abalone populations. The article also has implications for rhino populations, as a legal trade is currently proposed.

Keywords: rhino; system dynamics; illegal harvesting; predator-prey; Table Mountain National Park


 

 

Introduction

The South African abalone (Haliotis midae) fishery is experiencing a crisis. Illegal harvesting of abalone has escalated dramatically in recent years, to such an extent that the fishery was closed between 2008 and 2010.1 Several reasons for this escalation have been presented. For example, Raemaekers et al.2 argue that both the rise in abalone prices in the 1990s and the failure to include traditional fishers in the reform process, were drivers for the collapse in the fishery. Muchapondwa et al.1, however, found that drug use and corruption were major factors in the illegal trade in abalone.

The abalone fishery has a number of important features that characterise systems of illegal exploitation. Firstly, there is what is known as open-access to the resource. Here open-access implies that entrants have relatively free access to the resource and that species are subject to low levels of protection and enforcement and are subject to poaching.3 Secondly, the authorities seek to restrict access to the resource by patrolling the fishery, arresting offenders and enforcing some sort of penalty for the offence. Thirdly, the fishery is characterised by a complex system.2 This characterisation requires some form of integrated modelling to develop not only the biological dynamics of the abalone population, but also the dynamics of fishing effort.

Therefore, a model is developed here to capture each of these three features. The model is an open-access deterrence model and is developed using system dynamics modelling. Optimisation is used to calibrate the model to fit the historical data, so that unknown biological parameters may be estimated. A unique feature of the model is that it encapsulates decision-making by the resource custodian (in this case, the marine authority), thus enabling one not only to assess the implications for management of the abalone fishery, but also to see the potential implications for rhino management, as both rhino management and abalone management contain a number of similar features that will be discussed. The model is then used to answer 'what if' type policy questions to improve the sustainability of the abalone population.

 

Study site

The model is developed for the Table Mountain National Park in the Western Cape, South Africa, which falls within Zone E (Figure 1). Before the park was proclaimed in 2004, it was known as the Cape Peninsula National Park. In the same year the coastal waters surrounding the park were proclaimed as a marine protected area. However, fishing is still allowed in certain areas. This area was selected because it is close to an urban area (the City of Cape Town), has a good mix of legal fishing and illegal fishing, and is in close proximity to a number of fishing communities. The western areas of South Africa house some of the last remaining viable abalone populations, as many of the abalone populations to the southeast of the study area have already been depleted.

 

The model

Model attributes

The model comprises four features: (1) open-access modelling of poacher-population interactions using the Gordon-Schaefer model; (2) a deterrence model of poacher behaviour based on Becker's optimal enforcement model; (3) the marine authority's response to poaching; and (4) modelling of the fishery as an integrated complex system.

Open-access modelling

The Gordon-Schaefer open-access model is well described in the literature.4,5 Changes in stocks are a function of a biological growth f(x) less harvests (h):

x=f(x)-h Equation 1

Most frequently, f(x) is the logistic function although other density-dependent variants are possible.6 The harvests are represented by the standard Schaefer production function, which is a linear function of effort (E) and stock size (x):

h(E,x) = qEx. Equation 2

Here q is the catchability coefficient. Effort dynamics under open-access harvesting is a function of profitability, where greater profits attract additional entrants and fewer profits discourage entrants:

E = 0π, Equation 3

where π is a profit function relating prices to costs and is an adjustment parameter determining the rate at which effort adjusts to changes in profitability. In this model, an adapted adjustment parameter n'=0p is used, where p is the unit price of abalone, expressed as USD/tonnes. Costs on the other hand are a function of the effort expended in order to catch the resource.

Economics of crime and punishment

In a seminal article by Nobel laureate Gary Becker, it is argued that the supply of offences is a function of the probability of conviction per offence, and also the punishment per offence.7 The model has many applications in the economics literature. One example is an application to the economics of fraud by Van Heerden et al.8 This theory has been applied to fisheries by Sutinen and Anderson9, and more recently by Kuperan and Sutinen10. The Becker model was also used by Muchapondwa et al.1 to model the abalone fishery in South Africa.

Marine authority's objective

A unique feature of the model is the way that the marine authority's response to the poaching crisis is modelled. According to Goga11, up to 30% of the marine authority's operating budget is obtained through the sale of confiscated abalone on the open market. Revenues from the trade in abalone therefore play an important role in enforcement efforts. This role is modelled in the study by adopting a standard neoclassical approach, where the aim of the marine authority is to adapt enforcement effort in order to maximise the revenues obtained through the sale of confiscated abalone, subject to the constraints imposed by the abalone population as well as poaching effort. Some would argue that it is inappropriate for an authority tasked with resource conservation to maximise revenues from confiscations. However, this is very much aligned with the current emphasis of environmental authorities on sustainable resource use initiatives rather than conservation per se. It is therefore necessary to test the feasibility of this profit maximising objective for the sustainability of abalone stocks.

System dynamics modelling

The abalone fishery in South Africa may be viewed as a complex system, with many actors and role players. A system dynamics modelling approach provides a way of capturing those dynamics. A model was constructed to capture the interactions between poachers, the crew members, boat owners and the abalone population (Figure 2). The historical data span from 1980 to 2007, a time period of 27 years. The model is projected forward to the year 2100 to consider the effects of different management strategies on the dynamics of both abalone stocks and fishing effort.

Data

The data were derived from a number of sources. Edwards and Plagányi12 was the primary source of time series data on commercial catch per unit effort (CPUE) and commercial, recreational and illegal catches from 1980 to 2007. CPUE was standardised using a general linear modelling technique to eliminate differences between catch rates that are a result of any factor besides chance or differences in abundance (for example see Allen and Punsly13). These data were supplemented by data on illegal catches from 2003 to 200514 which were taken from confiscation records in Table Mountain National Park. In order to derive an estimate for the total illegal catch it was necessary to divide these amounts by the proportion of confiscations (bD).

It is unlikely that this proportion would be higher than 0.25, as data from Zones A to D suggest a range of between 0.06 and 0.25 (see Brandão and Butterworth15). In order to generate a lower bound estimate for illegal catch, the maximum proportion of confiscations was assumed to be 0.25. Therefore, illegal catch for the years 2003 to 2005 is estimated using:

Illegal catch t = Confiscations t / bD , for t = 2003,..,2005, Equation 4

where bD = 0.25 (Table 1). For the 2007 fishing season, it was assumed that trends in other zones were indicative of the situation in Zone E. The illegal catch in Zones A to D amounted to 927 tonnes in 200715 and the total allowable catch (TAC) was 125 tonnes16.

The TAC in Zone E was 12 tonnes in 2007, so apportioning by TAC gives an estimated illegal catch in Zone E of 89 tonnes in 2007 (12/125*927). Table 2 shows the poaching data for 2003-2007, estimated in this way. The methodology is coarse but shows that illegal fishing has increased dramatically over the period since 2003. The anecdotal evidence supports this assertion.1,2,16

 

 

Illegal fishing effort is estimated by dividing CPUE data12 into the illegal catch for that year. The CPUE data are for commercial fisheries. In the absence of other available data, it is necessary to assume that the CPUE for the illegal fishery would be similar. CPUE is expressed as kg/min. This unit was converted from a time-based measure of effort to a measure such as the number of fishing trips by dividing by the average length of a fishing trip.

Model equations

The exogenous parameters, values and references used are given in Table 1. The model equations are given in Table 3. The associated endogenous parameters are given in Table 4. The model comprises three components. The first component, the abalone population model, is a density-dependent logistic fisheries model. Fowler's density-dependent term was included to capture the effect of non-linear density dependence, following Milner-Gulland and Leader-Williams6. The logistic function has precedence in modelling South African abalone dynamics in Zone E12, thereby enabling access to specific biological parameters for this growth function. However, no known study has modelled the non-linear density-dependence factor for South African abalone. But it is possible to use optimisation to estimate the value of the density-dependent term by minimising the difference between the model data and the historical data using the historical data published in Edwards and Plagányi12, supplemented by the data in Table 1. The same technique is also used to estimate the value of the adjustment parameter n'.

 

 

The second component to the model is the fishing catch. Three types of fishing effort were present in the model over the historical period of the study (1980-2007). A recreational fishery was present during most of the time period, but was closed in 2004. A commercial fishery is also present in the study area, with the catch dependent on a TAC allocation determined annually by the fisheries authorities. In both these fisheries, catch is a function of the abalone abundance only. Naturally, however, recreational catches were set at zero from 2004 onwards. The illegal poaching, on the other hand, follows a standard Schaefer production function (Table 3). In other words, it is a function of the catchability coefficient, poaching effort and the available abalone population.

Illegal fishing is subject to enforcement effort by authorities. A third component to the model, therefore, is the authorities' response to illegal poaching. In standard deterrence models, there is one probability of detection that prevents illegal activity. However, in the South African abalone fishery, there are two detection probabilities, both of which are important to the model. The first probability is the one reported above, and the second is the probability of detection following an illegal poaching event. Once poaching occurs, abalone cannot be returned to the wild and an increase in the probability of detection after poaching therefore does not improve abalone populations. The seizure of illegally caught abalone by fisheries authorities is the most commonly reported on in the literature. In our model, therefore, there is both a probability of detection that prevents illegal harvesting, and a probability of detection that results in the seizure of abalone assets.

According to Goga11, fishery authorities sell abalone seized after illegal poaching. There is therefore an incentive to rather improve the probability of detection following an illegal poaching event, than to improve the probability of detection prior to a poaching event. Another factor to consider in the model is the penalty for transgression. Although abalone is confiscated, an additional penalty is levied. Some studies report high penalties and prison sentences for offenders. However, a recent study in Hangberg17 found that a fine levied to a repeat offender to prevent the possibility of a prison sentence was a mere ZAR20 000 (equivalent to USD2000 at the time at which the fine was imposed).

The marine authority's problem, according to neoclassical economic principles, is to maximise the present value of revenues from the confiscation of illegal catch:

where δ is the discount rate, bD is the probability of detection after a poaching event, hIt(.) is abalone confiscations and Vais the market value of abalone sales.

The change in abalone population (x) is a function of the population growth rate f(x) less harvests:

x=f(x)-hI(E,x)-hL(x), Equation 6

where hI(E,x) is the catch from illegal harvesting which is a function of poaching effort (E) and stock size x, and hL(x) is the catch from legal harvesting which is only a function of stock size.

The change in poaching effort (È) is a function of profitability from illegal harvesting π(·):

The objective of marine authorities is to vary the probability of detection prior to a poaching event (b) and the magnitude of the fine (f) in order to maximise the present value of revenues (costs (c) and prices (p) are held constant). The system dynamics model is used to solve this problem, using a discrete time variant of the net present value problem (Table 3).

 

Results

Baseline simulation

The model captures the increase in the illegal poaching of abalone from 2003 onwards. This increase occurred despite greater enforcement of marine fisheries zones. In 2005, Operation Neptune and Operation Trident ended, as did the Environmental Courts. Although these initiatives were in the Overberg, poaching in the Table Mountain National Park doubled from 27.5 tonnes to 68.7 tonnes (Table 2). This model indicates that, for the given parameter values, poaching has continued to increase.

The model provides a reasonably good fit to the illegal catch, effort and abalone abundance time series between 1980 and 2007 (Figure 3a-e). Figure 3 indicates that illegal fishing spiked after the closure of the recreational fishery. The increase in illegal poaching (Figure 3b) mirrors the declines in recreational fishing (Figure 3a). Recreational fishing peaked at approximately 120 tonnes, whereas illegal fishing peaked at approximately 90 tonnes.

Figure 3c indicates that, historically, the commercial fishery sectors have played a relatively small role in overall fishery catches. However, the most significant outcome of the model is that abalone stocks appear to have continued to decline since 2007, and are currently less than half of carrying capacity (Figure 3d). The decline in the illegal catch that is expected from 2015 onwards, it seems, is largely because of the lack of availability of abalone (Figure 3d) and spikes in poaching effort since 2003 (Figure 3e). According to the model, if current trends persist, abalone populations in Table Mountain National Park will be functionally extinct by 2050.

Policy simulations

The resource manager's challenge is to maximise the present value of abalone seizures by varying the probability of detection prior to a poaching event, as well as the fine for a transgression. One way of doing this is by patrolling no-take areas and also monitoring the departure of boats from the harbours.

It is important to emphasise that the following results hold for a resource manager's discount rate of less than 0.04 (4%). This is a model outcome. The marine authorities must place a high time preference on future stocks of abalone, in other words the sustainability of the resource. However, one would expect this from authorities that are custodians of abalone stocks.

The effect of varying the probability of detection prior to a poaching event (b) and the level of the fine (f) under costless enforcement are shown in Figure 4 in three figures: a bubble plot (Figure 4a), a line plot (Figure 4b) and an XY plot (Figure 4c).

The bubble plot (Figure 4a) indicates that the resource manager's profitability is maximised for high values of b and low values of f, and also low values of b and high values of f. Counter-intuitively, high values of both f and b result in the lowest net present values (NPVs) for resource managers, although these would result in the highest long-term abundance of abalone stocks.

The line plot (Figure 4b) indicates that the marine authorities' NPV is maximised at an abalone abundance of approximately 50% of carrying capacity (0.47K). This value equates more or less to the stock density at maximum sustainable yield for the density-dependent logistic growth function (0.49K). The XY data plot of b and f (Figure 4c) indicates that the highest NPV is achieved for a high probability of detection (b) and a low fine (f). Taken together, this implies that improving the probability of detection prior to a poaching event produces a sustainable stock density in the abalone fishery, while also maximising profits for the marine authority.

The first series of policy simulations assumes that enforcement is costless. A simple cost function was added to the marine authority's decision problem:

cM=bWc, Equation 8

where W is the enforcement effort of the marine authority. Enforcement costs are therefore an increasing function of the probability of detection prior to a poaching event (b). In the absence of other data, it is assumed that the enforcement costs per unit effort for the marine authority are the same as the cost per unit effort for the poaching vessel (c), and that the marine authority patrols once a day. Profit maximisation under this function is achieved by minimising the probability of detection prior to a poaching event, while maximising the level of the fine. The maximum payoff is USD0.63 million, compared with USD0.88 million under the zero enforcement cost outcome. However, at this level of enforcement effort the abalone population declines to zero by 2050, compared with populations stabilising at 47% of carrying capacity under the zero enforcement cost profit maximisation scenario.

As for the baseline, a Monte Carlo simulation was employed by varying the probability of detection prior to a poaching event (b) and the magnitude of the fine (f). This simulation indicated that only 3% of outcomes resulted in a positive NPV for the marine authority. Plotting these NPVs against biomass (from an ensemble of 750 realisations - Figure 4d) shows that, in contrast with the model of costless enforcement, profits for the resource authority are highest when stocks are allowed to deplete, and decline linearly as the biological population increases in relation to its carrying capacity. The XY plot under costly enforcement (Figure 4e) indicates that NPVs are highest under low probabilities of detection (b) and lowest under high probabilities of detection (although in absolute terms these probabilities of detection are much lower than under the costless enforcement scenario). Under costly enforcement, therefore, profit maximisation results in an unsustainable abalone population compared with profit maximisation under costless enforcement, and an incentive to minimise the probability of detection prior to a poaching event, compared with costless enforcement where there is an incentive to increase the probability of detection prior to a poaching event.

Sensitivity analysis

In order to test the sensitivity of the model outcomes to the new data on illegal catch in Zone E, the model was re-run using the illegal poaching data from Edwards and Plagányi12 and the shift from recreational to poaching in the model was set at zero. The model outputs were then compared with the new historical data for abalone abundance and illegal poaching effort (Figure 5). Figure 5 indicates that the sensitivity analysis replicates the decline in abalone abundance relatively satisfactorily (Figure 5a), and tracks changes in effort relatively accurately until around 1992 (Figure 5b). Thereafter, the model predicts a continued increase in poaching effort, whereas the data show a decline in poaching effort from 1993 onwards.

 

 

There are therefore some discrepancies between the model and the published historical data under the sensitivity run. However, more recent data in Brill and Raemaekers14 suggests that confiscations alone could be much higher than these published data. For example, Brill and Raemaeker's data indicate that reported confiscations in Zone E amounted to 17.2 tonnes of shucked abalone in 2005 (own calculations based on their data), which is considerably higher than the 1.4 tonnes reported in Edwards and Plagányi12 for the same period. Furthermore Brill and Raemaeker's data exclude undetected poaching events, so the possibility exists that poaching is even higher in Zone E than these estimates. Their data span the years 2000 to 2009, and therefore do not include the period from 1993 to 1999. Their data do, however, indicate a growing trend in confiscations over these 9 years, although this would only indicate an increase in illegal catch (and poaching effort as effort is proportional to catch in the Schaefer production function - see Equation 2) over that period if bD was stable or declining over that same period. Plagianyi et al.18 published time series data of a policing effort index which could provide an indication of likely changes in bD over time. The data show that the policing index remained constant between the years 2000 and 2004, but then decreased by 20 percentage points in 2004 and remained at this lower level until 2008. This finding indicates that illegal catch (and poaching effort) may have increased by even more than that modelled in this study (see Equation 4 - a decreasing bD implies an increase in illegal catch and poaching effort). However, this index is for Zones A to D and one can therefore not categorically state that the same trends would be observed in Zone E. In conclusion, there still is much uncertainty over the historical data, and further work in this area would be beneficial.

In spite of these uncertainties, the sensitivity analysis indicates that abalone abundance will decline, reaching functional extinction by 2080, which is slightly longer than that for the baseline model (2050). The model is therefore robust in predicting declines in abalone abundance, irrespective of whether or not there is a spike in illegal catches following the closure of the recreational fishery.

 

Implications for rhino conservation

There are many similarities between the abalone fishery and rhino conservation in South Africa. Both abalone and rhino horn are high-value commodities for which there is considerable demand on the Asian markets. Although abalone can be sold legally for about ZAR350/kg (USD35/kg wet 'in shell' weight), black market prices are considerably higher, with recent estimates at approximately ZAR2500/kg (USD250/kg). However, the trade in abalone is high volume. It was recently estimated that the illegal trade in abalone in the Eastern Cape Province of South Africa alone was worth USD50-100 million annually.19 The rhino horn trade fetches considerably higher prices, approximately USD65 000/kg in 2013, with some studies indicating prices as high as USD100 000/kg, but volumes are lower. Given that one horn weighs about 3 kg, and about 1000 rhinos were poached in South Africa in 2013, the implied illegal trade in rhino horn in South Africa was worth USD200-300 million in 2013.

Other similarities between the abalone fishery and rhino horn trade include that both products are relatively easy to transport; both species are slow-growing species and do not propagate easily; and as resources, they are difficult to protect - rhinos inhabit large areas that are often not adequately fenced off and abalone live in the ocean and consequently there are large areas of coastline to patrol. In sum, these types of resource demonstrate many features of an open-access system.

One notable difference between abalone and rhinos is that the abalone fishery in South Africa is characterised by a legal and illegal trade, whereas rhino horn is currently only traded illegally. However, there are strong lobby groups advocating for the legalisation of rhino horn trade. Observing the behaviour of the South African government as far as the South African abalone fishery is concerned therefore gives one some indication of how the government might respond if rhino horn were legally traded. There are, then, some important lessons that could be learnt from the abalone fishery.

The abalone fishery study indicates that it is important to distinguish between the probability of detection prior to the poaching offence, and the probability of detection following the poaching offence. Legalisation of trade in rhino horn would provide incentives to the South African government to increase the probability of detection following a poaching event. In the short term, this approach would not help to protect rhino populations, as the rhino would have already been killed. This approach will result in a race for rhinos and a 'trading on extinction' scenario in which profits are maximised over the short term to the detriment of the rhino population. This is similar to the 'banking on extinction' hypothesis of Mason et al.20, except that instead of stockpiling, goods are sold on the open market. Over the long term, the effect of changing the probability of detection after a poaching event for rhinos is uncertain. However, changing the probability of detection after a poaching event for abalone fisheries has not deterred poachers over the long term. In fact, poaching appears to have increased over the periods of heightened enforcement effort between 2000 and 2005. The solution for escaping the 'trading on extinction' scenario is to improve the probability of detection prior to a poaching event.

Under costless enforcement, profit maximisation provides an incentive to reduce the probability of detection prior to a poaching event, which results in a sustainable resource stock approximately at maximum sustainable yield. However, under costly enforcement, there is no economic incentive for resource custodians to improve the probability of detection prior to a poaching event. The abalone model indicates that the long-term sustainability of the resource is highly questionable under the following conditions: (1) a wildlife resource is subject to high levels of poaching; (2) there is a legal as well as an illegal trade in the resource; (3) the trade is highly lucrative; (4) profit maximisation principles are pursued by resource owners/custodians; and (5) enforcement is costly. Most of these conditions also hold for rhinos, were a legal trade to be allowed. A limitation of the abalone model is that only confiscation revenues, and not other sources of income, are included. For game farms or reserves, alternative sources of income such as that from dehorning and tourism may influence the outcome of the model. Some work has been done in this regard (see discussion section), although further work is required.

It is important also to recognise that a fundamental difference between abalone and rhinos is that abalone's primary benefit is through consumption. On the other hand, rhinos have a significant direct non-consumption benefit, namely tourism value. However both rhinos and abalone have a potential indirect non-consumptive benefit through ecosystem functioning. As Waldram et al.21 indicate, rhinos may reduce sward height in grasslands, thereby reducing the extent of bushfires in savanna regions. Abalone, on the other hand, relies on the sea urchin Parechinus angulosus as a refugia for juveniles,22 and therefore a well-functioning ecosystem is crucial to the survival of abalone. However, the removal of abalone may affect the emergence of epibenthic communities, as well as predatory fish diets.23 Therefore, tourism in both the marine environment as well as the savanna areas may be affected indirectly through an overall degeneration of ecosystem functioning associated with the disturbance of the ecological system. An assessment of a legal trade in both rhino horn and abalone should therefore also take these non-consumptive benefits into consideration.

 

Discussion

It has been shown here that a trading on extinction incentive exists in the management of abalone stocks. This finding implies that there is an incentive for wildlife authorities to maximise short-term revenues at the expense of the long-term sustainability of the abalone population. A similar effect was observed by Crookes and Blignaut24 in their model of the trade in rhino horn. They found that, although a legalisation of the trade increased the profitability of game farms significantly compared with a no-trade scenario, profits were higher under a policy outcome that resulted in the local extinction of the rhino population compared with profits under a sustainable supply of rhino. This outcome was a result of the fact that demand for rhino horn needed to decrease for sustainability to be achieved, which meant that the price of rhino horn would fall compared with demand from unsustainable supply.

It may seem paradoxical that a wildlife authority would have as its objective profit maximising, rather than another objective such as welfare maximisation, so two branches of literature are briefly discussed in support of this conclusion. Firstly, there is a significant body of literature that suggests that governments are motivated by profits when it comes to wildlife management. For example, Mayoral-Phillips, in his review of protected areas management in southern Africa, indicated that 'Governments, institutions, experts and stakeholders are rigidly following the rhetoric of "wildlife pays, wildlife stays", a form of wildlife privatisation of the commons'25(p.11). This privatisation does not imply that a national resource is placed in private sector hands, but rather implies that private sector principles of profit maximisation are applied (for example see De Fraja and Delbono26).

Other studies have also confirmed that there is a detrimental effect on the environment if the principles of profit maximisation are applied by government in certain instances. Bárcena-Ruiz and Garzón27 showed that when there are both government and private firms in product markets the environmental damage is greater than in the case of only private sector firms competing. Beladi and Chao28 also found a detrimental effect on the environment if government follows profit maximising principles. This outcome is a consequence of the failure of the government sector to prevent environmental damage when it acts as a monopoly, because they argue that it is characterised by inefficient management (see also Wang and Wang29). In all these examples, however, environmental impact is measured in terms of pollution emissions. This study is the first one known to observe this trend in abalone, and there is now a growing body of literature to suggest that profit maximisation under a legalised trade in wildlife may be detrimental to the sustainability of the wildlife populations. This is true at least for rhinos and abalone, and further work is required to establish whether or not this conclusion holds in other wildlife sectors as well.

 

Conclusions

An open-access deterrence model for the abalone fishery in Table Mountain National Park (Zone E) was presented here. Fishing has moved westwards in recent years, because many areas of the Overberg region are now so depleted that some areas no longer contain viable populations. This study is therefore important, as it provides a tool for marine authorities to better manage abalone populations. Under current conditions, abalone populations in Table Mountain National Park could be depleted by 2050, as a result of a spike in illegal fishing effort following the closure of the recreational fishery in 2003.

In contrast with Gordon's seminal article30, profit maximisation may not always result in the improved sustainability of wildlife populations. In the case of rhinos and abalone, a legalised trade must be accompanied by secondary policies, for the sustainability of the resource to be achieved. For rhinos, this secondary policy is consumer behaviour modification that reduces demand,24 whereas for abalone, it is improving the probability of detection prior to an offence. Under costly enforcement, the market does not provide the incentives to adopt these secondary policies, because profits are higher without them. If there is a legalised trade then there is an incentive for resource owners to switch to a non-sustainable (but profit maximising) solution - termed the 'trading on extinction' effect. There is a need to emphasise and promote the non-consumptive benefits of the resources in question, as well as, in the case of abalone, address the causes of poaching rather than the consequences of poaching.

 

Acknowledgements

This article forms part of a 3-year project studying new approaches to model the economics of scarce resources. Funding from the National Research Foundation (South Africa) is gratefully acknowledged.

 

References

1. Muchapondwa E, Brick K, Visser M. Abalone conservation in the presence of drug use and corruption: Implications for its management in South Africa. Int J Sust Econ. 2014;6(2):201-216. http://dx.doi.org/10.1504/ijse.2014.060348        [ Links ]

2. Raemaekers S, Hauck M, Bürgener M, Mackenzie A, Maharaj G, Plagányi EE, et al. Review of the causes of the rise of the illegal South African abalone fishery and consequent closure of the rights-based fishery. Ocean Coast Manage. 2011;54:433-445. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ocecoaman.2011.02.001        [ Links ]

3. Hall RJ, Milner-Gulland EJ, Courchamp F. Endangering the endangered: The effects of perceived rarity on species exploitation. Conserv Lett. 2008;1:75-81. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1755-263X.2008.00013.x        [ Links ]

4. Wilen JE. Common property resources and the dynamics of overexploitation: The case of the North Pacific fur seal. University of British Columbia Resources Paper No. 3. 1976; September.         [ Links ]

5. Bj0rndal T, Conrad JM. The dynamics of an open-access fishery. Can J Economics. 1987;20:74-85. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/135232        [ Links ]

6. Milner-Gulland EJ, Leader-Williams N. A model of incentives for the illegal exploitation of black rhinos and elephants: Poaching pays in Luangwa Valley, Zambia. J Appl Ecol. 1992;29:388-401. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2404508        [ Links ]

7. Becker G. Crime and punishment: An economic approach. J Polit Econ. 1968;76(2):169-217. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/259394        [ Links ]

8. Van Heerden JH, Blignaut JN, Groenendijk NS. On the shady side of economics. S Afr J Econ Manag Sci. 1999;2(2):207-221.         [ Links ]

9. Sutinen JG, Andersen P. The economics of fisheries law enforcement. Land Econ. 1985;61(4):387-397. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3146156        [ Links ]

10. Kuperan K, Sutinen J. Blue water crime: Deterrence, legitimacy, and compliance, in fisheries. Law Soc Rev. 1998;32(2):309-338. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/827765        [ Links ]

11. Goga K. The illegal abalone trade in the Western Cape. ISS Paper 261. Pretoria: Institute for Security Studies; 2014.         [ Links ]

12. Edwards CTT, Plagányi ÉE. Participatory assessment of the South African abalone resource and its impact on predicted population trajectories. S Afr J Sci. 2008;104:185-191.         [ Links ]

13. Allen R, Punsly R. Catch rates as indices of abundance of yellowfin tuna, Thunnus albacares, in the eastern Pacific Ocean. Bull Inter-Amer Trop Tuna Comm. 1984;18(4):301-379.         [ Links ]

14. Brill GC, Raemaekers SJPN. A decade of illegal fishing in Table Mountain National Park (2000-2009): Trends in the illicit harvest of abalone Haliotis midae and West Coast rock lobster Jasus lalandii. Afr J Mar Sci. 2013;35(4):491-500. http://dx.doi.org/10.2989/1814232X.2013.850443        [ Links ]

15. Brandão A, Butterworth DS. Results for the abalone spatial- and age-structured assessment model for Zones A, B, C and D in 2013. Working Group document FISHERIES/2013/AUG/SWG-AB/12. Cape Town: Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries; 2013.         [ Links ]

16. Hauck M, Gallardo-Fernández GL. Crises in the South African abalone and Chilean loco fisheries: Shared challenges and prospects. Mar Stud. 2013;12:3. http://dx.doi.org/10.1186/2212-9790-12-3        [ Links ]

17. De Greef K. The booming illegal abalone fishery in Hangberg: Tough lessons for small-scale fisheries governance in South Africa [MSc dissertation]. Cape Town: University of Cape Town; 2013.         [ Links ]

18. Plagányi É, Butterworth D, Burgener M. Illegal and unreported fishing on abalone: Quantifying the extent using a fully integrated assessment model. Fish Res. 2011;107:221-232. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.fishres.2010.11.005        [ Links ]

19. John Webb. Perlemoen poachers [television broadcast]. Carte Blanche. Johannesburg: M-Net; 2014 October 02.         [ Links ]

20. Mason CF, Bulte EH, Horan RD. Banking on extinction: Endangered species and speculation. Oxford Rev Econ Pol. 2012;28(1):180-192. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/grs006        [ Links ]

21. Waldram MS, Bond WJ, Stock WD. Ecological engineering by a mega-grazer: White rhino impacts on a South African savanna. Ecosystems. 2008;11:101-112. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10021-007-9109-9        [ Links ]

22. Blamey LK, Plagányi ÉE, Branch GM. Was overfishing of predatory fish responsible for a lobster-induced regime shift in the Benguela? Ecol Mod. 2014;273:140-150. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2013.11.004        [ Links ]

23. Blamey LK, Branch GM, Reaugh-Flower KE. Temporal changes in kelp forest benthic communities following an invasion by the rock lobster Jasus lalandii. Afr J Mar Sci. 2010;32(3):481-490. http://dx.doi.org/10.2989/1814232X.2010.538138        [ Links ]

24. Crookes DJ, Blignaut JN. Debunking the myth that a legal trade will solve the rhino horn crisis: A system dynamics model for market demand. J Nat Conserv. 2015;28:11-18. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jnc.2015.08.001        [ Links ]

25. Mayoral-Phillips AJ. Transboundary areas in southern Africa: Meeting the needs of conservation or development? Paper presented at: The Ninth Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property; 2002 June 17-21; Victoria Falls, Zimbabwe. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10108-006-9006-y        [ Links ]

26. De Fraja G, Delbono F. Alternative strategies of a public enterprise in oligopoly. Oxford Econ Pap. 1989;41(2):302-311.         [ Links ]

27. Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB. Mixed oligopoly and environmental policy. Span Econ Rev. 2006;8:139-160. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10108-006-9006-y        [ Links ]

28. Beladi H, Chao C-C. Does privatization improve the environment? Econ Lett. 2006;93:343-347. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2006.06.005        [ Links ]

29. Wang LFS, Wang J. Environmental taxes in a differentiated mixed duopoly. Econ Syst. 2009;33:389-396. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecosys.2009.08.002        [ Links ]

30. Gordon HS. Economic theory of a common-property resource: The fishery. J Polit Econ. 1954;62:124-142. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/257497        [ Links ]

31. De Greef K, Raemaekers S. South Africa's illicit abalone trade: An updated overview and knowledge gap analysis. Cambridge: TRAFFIC International; 2014.         [ Links ]

 

 

Correspondence:
Douglas Crookes
Department of Economics, University of Pretoria
Private Bag X20, Hatfield 0028, South Africa
dcrookes@outlook.com

Received: 23 June 2015
Revised: 05 Aug. 2015
Accepted: 09 Oct. 2015

Creative Commons License Todo el contenido de esta revista, excepto dónde está identificado, está bajo una Licencia Creative Commons